Purchasing Power Parity Estimates for Canada

Purchasing Power Parity Estimates for Canada and Implications for Volume Comparisons
Katharine Kemp and Gaston Levesque
Statistics Canada

Abstract

Interest in purchasing power parities comes from policy, analytical and private sector uses and from the widespread recognition that official market exchange rates are inadequate tools for purposes of comparing price levels among countries. Governments and international agencies are increasingly interested in the rankings of countries in terms of their output for purposes of international comparisons. Academic and private sector interests continue to explore alternative measures for comparison, and such direct uses as assessing the relative costs of setting up a business in different countries, or legal and insurance settlements in different currencies. A number of PPP measures have been calculated, from which are derived different results for inter-country price levels and the reciprocal volume or real comparisons. PPPs as inter-country deflators are preferable to the exchange rate based comparisons on both conceptual and empirical grounds. The paper focuses on differences in the Canada/US comparisons using the multilateral and bilateral studies of the OECD-EUROSTAT PURCHASING Power Parity Programme, and touches on the results obtained through the much broader-based World PENN Tables.
 
 

Introduction

With increasing globalization and economic interdependence among countries, the relative performance of countries in terms of economic output and structure is becoming increasingly important to both governments and international agencies. The development of new trade associations, such as the Free Trade Agreement (FTA), the North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA), the Asia-Pacific Economic Co-operation (APEC), General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade, Uruguay round (GATT) have been generating increasing requirements for macroeconomic tools which can measure, across countries, output, productivity, investment, and income distributions, to name a few. Recognition of the importance of spatial comparisons has also been identified in the 1993 international System of National Accounts “to compare standards of living, levels of economic development or levels of productivity and also to compare the price levels in different countries when prices are converted at exchange rates”. Requirements for such macroeconomic tools emphasize the importance of the PPPs.

Purchasing power parities interest policy and macroeconomic analysts as measures of differences in price levels among countries. They can be compared to market exchange rates and the extent to which a country's currency is "over" or "under" valued can be monitored over time, in terms of what can actually be purchased in the other country. Comparison with exchange rates over time provides a measure of the volatility of currencies on exchange markets. Private companies can use PPPs to assess how much it would cost to set up a firm or plant in another country and assist the decision as to where the most appropriate location would be from an economic perspective. Similarly, they can be used to determine the type of allowance schedule that would be appropriate to maintain an employee who is moved from one country to another. Other uses have been made of the PPPs in valuing insurance claims or legal settlements that involve parties in different countries. The Estonian ferry disaster of a few years ago was a good example. Passengers came from different countries and the financial settlements involved, required currency conversion by the insurance companies.

A key analytic use for the PPPs is as a set of deflators to convert the Gross Domestic Product for one or more countries expressed in its own currency to a set of expenditures expressed in a common currency such as the currency of a base country or group of countries. By means of this deflation process, real or volume measures for different countries can be compared. Converting such volume measures to a per person basis provides equivalent measurements to rank countries’ output. Beginning in 1993, for example, the World Bank started publishing the rankings of countries based on output derived using PPP conversions. Previously exchange rates had been used as price converters in establishing such rankings. With the change to the PPPs as currency converters, the share of developing countries in the "world" economy grew substantially. This was due in large part to the fact that services tend to cost much less in such developing countries, contributing to lower PPPs for the GDP as a whole, and resulting in higher measurements of real output and correspondingly higher GDP per person.

As a further recent example of such uses of the volume comparisons, a recent paper presented in Ottawa by Professor Robert Summers 1 drawing on the results of the World PENN Table identified some lines of inquiry which would be interesting in the Canada/US context as well. These include looking at output per employed person, leaving out components which he called “regrettable necessities” (example, defence expenditures) and using only the remaining GDP components. Given the difference in the share of the GDP that such expenditures represent in Canada versus the US, this comparison would raise the relative output of Canada quite a bit. Other suggestions are to use only current expenditure and omit capital investment from the comparisons. Investment, which is saving for the future, could be omitted for some analytic purposes, where current expenditure is of more interest. Yet another use has recently been demonstrated by Michael Wolfson 2, in which he is comparing PPP deflated income distributions between Canada and the US, with interesting findings as to what lies behind the average income in the two countries. Interest has been increasing as well in developing PPPs at an industry or production level, as well as the final expenditure level, as is discussed here. With production- based or industry level PPPs, some light could be shed on productivity comparisons. This work is at a very early stage, but is potentially very interesting.

Purchasing power parities (PPPs), which have been under development since the 1950s, provide price level comparisons among countries from which can be derived the output measures used for such comparative analysis. These are theoretically more appropriate intercountry price comparisons than market exchange rates which can be influenced by many factors in addition to price levels among countries, such as fuel shortages, political uncertainties, or the deficit or debt of particular countries. Services, in particular, are not traded in the same way as goods so that their prices are unlikely to parallel the exchange rates between countries. Economic theory suggests that for internationally traded, domestically produced goods and services, the PPPs and exchange rates will tend to equalize in the long run. Exchange rates, however, can fluctuate widely in short periods. Sometimes, a country intentionally devalues its currency, or dramatic shifts can occur due to exogenous factors (the recent case of Mexico).The exchange rates are, however, appropriate for some purposes, for example, when analyzing international capital markets where the exchange rate is the price to be paid. With the calculation of the PPPs, actual price differences among countries are identified and these measures and the volume measures derived from them are much more precise and stable over time. The OECD-EUROSTAT multilateral PPP program includes all members of the OECD and EUROSTAT (some differences in the combinations of countries over the period of the programme) and the most recent PENN World Table includes price and real output comparisons for about 150 countries. In Canada, we tend to be most interested in US /Canada comparisons. These studies all present different results for the US and Canada which are the subject of this discussion.

PPPs measuring world spatial comparisons are analogous to the use and construction of implicit price indexes in national temporal comparisons of Gross Domestic Product. They allow expenditures in different countries to be expressed in the same set of prices (a base set of prices), permitting volume or real comparisons among countries to be derived. They are measured at the level of some 220 goods and services, known as the basic heading level. These micro PPPs are weighted using national expenditures (the weighting method depends on the particular formula used) to derive a macro PPP for the GDP in total. Recognized difficulties and differences exist in their measurement and this paper assesses some of the factors and implications, which affect the three comparisons, focussing on the reliability of the Canada/US data.

Three sets of results compare Canada to the US. From the OECD-EUROSTAT Programme of benchmark studies, a multilateral comparison for the OECD and EUROSTAT countries provides a relationship for Canada PPPs versus those of the US. From the same program, separate (direct) bilateral studies for the US and Canada have been undertaken, drawing out the specifications and prices which are comparable and representative in these two countries and using GDP expenditures for only these countries. OECD reference studies were done in 1980, 1985, 1990, and 1993. The 1996 results are forthcoming later in 1998. The World PENN Tables, including data for 152 countries (known as PWT5.6a) also contain comparative data for the US and Canada. From the OECD-EUROSTAT benchmark studies, time series have been projected to produce annual PPPs. The OECD Programme publishes time series for the multilateral comparisons, Statistics Canada publishes time series for the Canada/US bilateral comparisons and the World PENN Tables publish annual data for the countries included in their comparisons. Updated data for the PENN tables are expected in the next few weeks, but for now these tables for the latest version (PWT5.6a) show time series to 1992.

 

(Tables and Charts of three comparisons and the exchange rate and the volume comparisons follow).

Three PPP comparisons and the exchange rate


PPPs Canada/US , Gross Domestic Product

Canadian dollars per US dollar
 

Year OECD multilateral OECD bilateral STC (projections) PENN Mark 5.6a Market Exchange rate
1980 1.27 1.21 1.15 1.17
1981 1.28 1.20 1.16 1.20
1982 1.31 1.21 1.21 1.23
1983 1.32 1.24 1.22 1.23
1984 1.30 1.25 1.22 1.30
1985 1.29 1.24 1.21 1.37
1986 1.29 1.23 1.21 1.39
1987 1.30 1.23 1.21 1.33
1988 1.31 1.25 1.21 1.23
1989 1.32 1.23 1.21 1.18
1990 1.30 1.22 1.21 1.17
1991 1.29 1.23 1.19 1.15
1992 1.28 1.23 1.18 1.21
1993 1.26 1.23    
1994 1.25 1.21    
1995 1.24 1.20    
1996 1.22      

Bolded data indicates years of OECD-EUROSTAT benchmark studies 1996 is a projection. The benchmark study is not complete.

 

 

Real Gross Domestic Product per head, Canada/US


Derived from:

Year OECD multilateral OECD Bilateral (projections) PENN Mark 5.6a $ Current from PENN data PENN adjusted with $Can+$US from OECD Vol 1
1980 82.3 89.7 81.08 91.28
1981 83.7 90.7 81.55 92.43
1982 82.6 90.9 76.48 89.78
1983 82.7 89.4 75.52 88.99
1984 83.0 87.6 74.95 87.96
1985 83.7 89.1 77.84 89.12
1986 84.4 88.4 76.77 88.95
1987 84.4 90.3 79.08 91.28
1988 85.7 91.9 80.39 92.80
1989 83.6 92.7 80.35 91.65
1990 81.9 88.7 78.74 88.88
1991 81.5 86.6 77.54 88.26
1992 79.1 84.1 76.29 85.67
1993 78.7 82.5    
1994 78.8 82.5    
1995 78.8 82.5    
1996 77.4 80.4    

1. Bolded data indicates years of OECD-EUROSTAT benchmark studies.
2. 1996 is a projection. The benchmark study is not yet complete.
3. OECD columns are based on current dollar data; PENN data has been adjusted to use Canada and US published data from OECD National Accounts, Vol I.

 

 

Description

In general, some axiomatic properties are required in spatial comparisons (as are also required in time series, depending on the purpose of the price indexes). For example, the results must be transitive. This means that the results will be consistent whichever country (or group of countries) is used as the base. This requirement leads to the use of Fisher formula price ratios between countries. The Fisher formula also has a drawback for some purposes in that the derived volume components do not sum to the total volume for the GDP. For some analysis this is not a serious concern while for other types of analysis, such consistency in aggregation is important. Another requirement is factor reversibility; that is, the restatement of the value series deflated by the PPPs will yield the volume indexes and vice versa, with no remainder.

The OECD multilateral benchmark studies, in which all countries are related to each other and to the whole, incorporate price and expenditure data from all the countries included in the comparisons. Comparisons (PPPs) between any two countries therefore take into account the economic structures of all countries in the comparison. Each PPP takes into account the market composition and economic structures of all countries in the comparison, not just the goods and services on the markets being compared. Complexities arise from the different markets for consumer and investment and the variety of goods and services consumed in all the countries. The potential exists for strong negative or unpredictable correlations between price and quantity on a cross-country basis. Otherwise stated, a relative price increase between two countries gives little intuitive feel for what the relative quantity impact might be, unlike the case in time series where a rise in price for an item is expected to produce substitution effects, decreasing the quantity purchased. This phenomenon in a spatial context leads to much wider differences than are seen in time series between the Laspeyres and Paasche indexes. (In spatial comparisons, the base or given country’s weights are used to compile the PPPs)

Following a look at the three sets of results for the Canada /US comparisons of price and volume, this paper reviews the factors and their impacts which contribute to the differences in levels and trends of these PPPs and volume comparisons and describes some initiatives underway to develop and improve the comparisons. The discussion concerns the macro level of the PPPs, as well as estimation procedures at more detailed levels (micro PPPs).

 

Results

The first table and chart show results of the three Canada/US PPP comparisons for the period 1981-1995, 3 and the exchange rate, all in Canadian dollars per US dollar. The PPPs in all cases refer to the Gross Domestic Product, that is, micro PPPs weighted with GDP expenditure categories. The first column presents the time series created by the OECD from its benchmark studies (bolded) for all countries in the multilateral comparisons. For this multilateral comparison, the PPP projections are calculated using the ratio of the growth rates of the Implicit Price Indexes for the Canadian and US GDPs. The years between benchmarks use forward projections for years near the earlier period and retro-projections for years nearer the later benchmark. The second column also uses the results of the OECD benchmark studies in the same years but for the direct bilateral Canada/US comparisons. In this case, the PPPs are projected and interpolated in all the intervening years, weighting the PPPs projected forward and backwards between benchmarks to smooth the transition. Again, the ratio of the growth rates of the IPIs for Canada and the US are used as projectors of the PPPs, but at the level of the 55 published categories. The PENN World Table brings together comparisons in space and time, using adjustment factors to convert or smooth time series and benchmark data and to fill in gaps where actual country data are missing. The results cannot be precisely compared with the OECD studies due to the inclusion of price and expenditure data for many more countries. Incorporating the economic structures and prices for 150 countries also affects the relationship between each pair of countries in the study.

In 1985, the bilateral PPP for Canada (US=100) was 1.24 at the level of the GDP, compared with the multilateral results of 1.29. In 1990, the bilateral result was 1.22, compared with multilateral result of 1.30. In 1993, a limited bilateral US/Can study was undertaken, yielding a bilateral PPP of 1.23 compared to 1.26 for the multilateral result at the level of GDP. The PENN result was 1.21 in 1985 and 1990, closer to the bilateral result.

Differences exist between the Canada/US PPPs shown by the OECD-EUROSTAT multilateral and bilateral benchmark results, with the PPPs from the bilateral results always lower than the multilateral results. This means, it takes relatively fewer Canadian dollars in Canada to buy the same amount as one US dollar purchases in Canada, across all the GDP components, when looking at the bilateral results than when using the multilateral results. Such results imply an intuitive result that the closer match of specifications, prices, markets, and economic structures between the two countries brings the price comparisons closer together.

In the series calculated for the PENN real output, the current price estimates have been adjusted, substituting the national published estimates for GDP in current dollars and population 4 for the data shown in the PENN Table itself. (PWT 5.6a). This brings the volume measure to levels just above those for the bilateral study, as would be expected from the slightly lower PPPs.

A consistent result demonstrated by the three time series of volumes for Canada relative to the US, is that the output per head has been declining since 1990. In this period both Canada and the US experienced slowdowns in growth. If the hypothesis that Canada’s cycle is steeper and slower to recover, the volume results are plausible.. Some other factors which also affected the downward trend were downward data revisions in the GDP expenditure series in Canada and an upward revision to the population counts, following the 1991 census of population.

 

PPP estimations

Many empirical considerations, techniques and measurement approaches are involved in the estimation of the PPPs and the derived volume estimates, both for the benchmark studies, and for the interpolated time series. The price index theory and choice of formula issues are largely left for discussion elsewhere. The purpose of this discussion is to look at more statistical estimation aspects, which play a critical role in the comparative result.

It should be noted first, that spatial price comparisons contain all the same issues and problems that are found in time series, and usually they are much more complex. As in time series, the measurement of non-market services (government health and education) causes particular difficulty. These are measured using the same convention as in time series, that is, inputs are used to measure outputs. A major shortcoming of the input-cost approach is that it does not account for differences in productivity levels among countries. Wage rates and purchased goods and services as well as capital consumption allowances must be estimated. Does the doctor’s wage rate in different countries reflect the increased or decreased productivity of having fewer tools and less equipment to work with? This is a more serious problem spatially than in time series, where the equipment and technology would be expected to change more slowly, not causing major shifts in productivity over time. Spatially, depending on the countries being compared, wide differences are possible. No adjustment for intercountry productivity differences are attempted when using these inputs as proxy measures for the desired outputs, although research is ongoing in this area. Such adjustments could be very significant, depending on the GDP component and countries being compared. These are often referred to as “comparison-resistant” goods. The closer countries’ economic, institutional and market structures are, the less will be the concern with such issues.

The individual price comparisons among countries are the key element in the PPP estimations. It is much more difficult to measure price differences across space than through time. Growth rates for one country’s market through time are easier to identify than differences in price levels across markets at a point in time. The latter require item specifications that are sufficiently representative of a country’s consumption and at the same time are comparable among countries. The specifications developed and used in the OECD-EUROSTAT program tend to be Euro-centric, that is, they are more representative of consumption in the western European countries than they are of non- European countries, such as North America, Australia, New Zealand, or Japan.
 

Bias

Bias concerns statisticians in spatial comparisons even more than in time series. Bias can be introduced at many different levels. To increase comparability and reduce possible biases in the comparisons, the prices incorporated rely on a combination of the following characteristics and filters. Generic and specific specifications are used. Specific specifications are quoted in terms of manufacturer and model number and produce the most exact matches, but are not always available among countries, or may not be typical of spending patterns. To fill in gaps, more generic specifications are combined, in which the characteristics of the item to be priced are described. While these specifications lead to price estimations for representative goods and services in most countries, they also embody quality differences between countries. They may therefore be closer to a unit value comparison, rather than a measurement of pure price differentials. A third approach used is the functional equivalence group, specifications which lie between the specific brand and model (which may not be typical or even available in certain markets) and the generic specifications which are not specific enough. The functional equivalence approach identifies more technical characteristics of the good and a range of “qualities” (high end, popular-priced, etc.) so that representativity can be improved in individual countries. To counterbalance bias that may be introduced, each country prices both typical items in its market and atypical items which are representative in another country. It is hoped that in combining the typical item PPP by the atypical one, the result should be reasonably objective. Possible errors may still arise if the degree of bias is different in the two directions, due, for example, to the type of outlet chosen in different countries, or the sample sizes. As is often the case, the statisticians count on offsetting errors in such comparisons. Bias is still less of a problem between Canada and the US than among other countries, however.
 

Why are these results different

In addition to the price issues raised above, a number of other factors can influence the results. In the OECD-EUROSTAT comparisons, the individual PPPs themselves are not revised. However, the extent and timing of revisions to National Accounts expenditure data can and do affect the volume comparisons. In Canada, the biggest downward revision in the GDP in at least 25 years occurred in 1990 (1.2%). This was also the year of a benchmark study. The results of the census of population conducted every 5 years are introduced when the results become available. For the intervening years, the population is extrapolated. When the 1991 results became available, the projections were found to be too low, due to a technical undercounting, and the population counts were raised by 4% for the census year, and adjusted for the entire series. The effect of these two revisions was to lower output per person by 5-6%. In the bilateral time series constructed in Statistics Canada the macro PPPs are revised through revisions that re-weight the micro PPPs. The accuracy of population counts in other countries is hard to evaluate. Intuitively, we expect undercoverage in the United States as a result of the number of illegal residents in the country. Furthermore, if all the comparisons are not using data at the same point of timeliness (i.e preliminary or revised estimates), the results will be different. For example, in the PENN work, the data on population and GDP may be taken from indirect sources, and lack the latest revisions, as noted above. Canada has just incorporated a historical revision based on the 1993 international guidelines for the System of National Accounts. These are not yet incorporated for countries in the published OECD version of National Accounts nor are they incorporated in the PPP comparisons. To the extent that other countries are on a different time schedule, the comparisons among countries will be less accurate to some extent.

The accuracy of the National Accounts expenditure data in all countries in the comparisons and the classification system used for the expenditures are significant factors. The United States, for example, has never been an adherent of the System of National Accounts, although they are moving closer to it. They do special tables for the OECD incorporating some special classes of expenditure, which are not available in their National Income and Product Accounts. As a result, some expenditure matches are not as precise as would be desirable. The PPPs are calculated by the OECD-EUROSTAT programme using two classifications, the System of National Accounts (SNA) which is an expenditure classification, and the ICP, the consumption-based classification used in the United Nations’ International Comparison Program and incorporated in the PENN tables. These classification differences impact results for goods and services paid for by government and consumed by individuals., such as health and education. The ICP results are more relevant in cases where the analytical emphasis is on the consumer.

The classification system used for the expenditure data, especially for personal expenditure categories is moving towards the COICOP, that is, the SNA 1993 classification to be adopted by all countries. This should eventually improve the consistency of the program among all the countries.

The definitions and measurements of key concepts embedded in the National Accounts expenditures and the accuracy of the surveys and administrative data sources also play a role in the measurements. We have seen a growing gap between unemployment rates for Canada and the US. This may reflect definitional differences, undercounts, or measurement tools to a greater or lesser extent. Again, expectations are that such differences would be less between the US and Canada than between many other country comparisons.
 

Canada/US PPPs

  • Benchmarks

Most of the discussion concerns the two OECD comparisons: Canada/US from the multilateral comparison and from the bilateral comparison. The PENN tables are constructed differently, taking into account many more countries and deriving some estimates using statistical methods rather than direct price data. Because of the similarity in tastes, markets and institutions between Canada and the United States, the OECD bilateral comparison is the most robust comparison. This similarity, which is reflected in expenditure baskets in both countries minimizes the bias due to the aggregation process. The range of goods and services consumed are similar, item specifications can be well matched, similar outlets are the source of purchases in the two countries, income levels are broadly similar and statistical classifications and definitions are also very similar in many instances. This is one set of factors contributing to the strength of the comparisons for the benchmark studies. Still, the comparisons are faced with different types of price data banks in the two countries, where in Canada we are using a much thinner range of prices and in the US it is a probability sample, not necessarily geared to a spatial comparison.

  • Time series

Price index theory tells us that an index number problem always exists. Changing price structures over time and through space alter the trend of a price index and rebasing of price series is necessary to bring the growth rates into line. This is true of spatial comparisons as well as time series. When we compare relative rates of growth using national GDP and those implied from successive PPP benchmark studies, the change in price structures both within countries over time and among countries spatially has the effect that the projected growth rates and new benchmark levels will not match. The implication is that any projection of the time series can never be an accurate reflection of new PPP levels. The projection of the multilateral PPPs, using the growth rates of each country’s GDP results in apparent discontinuities whenever the benchmark results are completed. These are not usually severe, but they do represent a conceptual issue. In the bilateral series the smoothing process was not based on index number theory, but rather averages out the trend between the benchmark levels, projecting ahead from the most recent study until the results are completed. The PPPs using these results have stayed within a narrower band.

Another point concerns the price indexes embedded in the GDP deflator. Recent discussion suggests that the CPI for the US has been overstated for the past few years. One reason cited is that it does not take adequate account of changes in outlets where consumer purchases are made. (Department stores to “big box” bulk purchasing outlets, for example). Other factors mentioned include the micro and macro aggregation formulas, as well as the treatment of the introduction of new goods and the continuing issue of quality change adjustments. The suggestion has been made that the Canadian CPI is less biased upwards. If this hypothesis holds, the lower rate of inflation in Canada may be at least partly illusory. The comparison between the two CPIs is, however, bringing down the level of the projected PPP time series after the latest benchmark study, since the CPI is used to measure prices for about two-thirds of the GDP. With lower PPPs we would intuitively expect the reciprocal volume series to rise in Canada relative to the US. The charts show otherwise. Behind the trend shown are two other factors: a revision in the population estimates for Canada, which were raised as a result of the 1991 census, bringing down the GDP per person as well the downward revision in the GDP estimates for 1990. Combined these two revisions lowered the GDP per head in Canada by almost 6%.
 

Thoughts for the future

 

Although strong support exists to use PPPs rather than market exchange rates in comparing and analyzing price levels and real or volume comparisons among countries, it is recognized that improvements are needed at the micro levels. More confidence can be placed at the macro GDP level in the comparisons, while some components are more problematic (as is also true in the time series). Several initiatives are underway. These include the establishment of a working group for non-European countries to examine and adapt the specifications and pricing methods particularly in the area of personal consumption, so as to reflect the tastes and markets of the different component countries. More analytical resources could be applied to examine unusual results in different studies for different countries and try to explain or improve them. Other data sources are becoming available which can be utilized. These include scanner data, which will provide a much broader range of price data than are currently collected in most countries. Additional data are available through the international agencies, for example, for automobile sales and direct volume measures for items such as telephone calls, from which PPPs could be implicitly derived. Examination of both the volume side and the price comparisons may help strengthen the analysis as well for specific components. Further use can be made of regression and hedonic methods as is now applied to rents, for example, as well as the model approach used for parts of construction. Some thought is being given to productivity adjustment factors where inputs are used, but this has been an issue difficult to overcome in time series as well.

A number of concerns have been identified in undertaking spatial comparisons of price and volume among countries. We believe that progress is possible and that the results will continue to improve, as analysts continue to identify better approaches to the desired measures, as has been the case with time series. Finally, the PPP comparisons and their reciprocal volume measures at aggregated levels are better price converters than exchange rates and the direct bilateral Canada/US results are believed to be the most robust.

 


Foot Notes

  1 Robert Summers and Alan Heston, The World distribution of Wellbeing Dissected, University of Pennsylvania

  2 Michael Wolfson and Brian B. Murphy, New views on inequality trends in Canada and the United States, Monthly Labor Review, April 1998, Bureau of Labor Statistics, Washington, D.C.

  3 The PENN tables are available to 1992; updated data are expected within weeks.

  4 As presented and updated by countries in the OECD National Accounts, Volume I(1996 edition)

TopHomeSearchContact Us
Last Update: Tuesday, March 02, 2004 |