W. Craig Riddell
University of British Columbia and CIAR
Andrew Sharpe
Centre for the Study of Living Standards
 
From Canada's viewpoint, one of the most important labour market developments
in the past 15 years has been the divergence of the Canadian and American
unemployment rates after 1981. From 1948 to 1981, the unemployment rate in Canada
was, on average, the same as that in the United States. In the 1980s, the Canadian
unemployment rate averaged more than 2 percentage points higher than the American
rate, with the gap rising to 4 points in the 1990s. A definitive explanation of this
development has eluded researchers.
High levels of unemployment are a great concern to many Canadians. Public
opinion polls typically show that reducing unemployment is considered our number one
priority. Canada has not been the only country to experience rising levels of
unemployment during the past several decades. Indeed, many European countries have
experienced larger increases in unemployment than has Canada. Nonetheless, the U.S.
experience provides the most relevant benchmark for Canada. Because of the many
similarities in the two countries, we are naturally interested in knowing why the United
States has been able to keep unemployment well below the Canadian level.
In 1995, the newly established Centre for the Study of Living Standards (CSLS)
initiated a research project on the Canada-US unemployment rate gap. The project
brought together labour economists from both Canada and the United States with the
objective of shedding light on this important national issue. This volume represents the
outcome of the project. It contains revised versions of papers presented at a conference,
co-sponsored by the Canadian Employment Research Forum, held in Ottawa on February
9-10, 1996.
The objectives of this introductory article are twofold. First, we set the scene for
the articles that follow by providing context, a framework for situating explanations of
the gap, and an overview of the most frequently evoked explanations. Second, we briefly
summarize the key contributions of the papers in this volume, both to our knowledge of
the two labour markets and to our understanding of the unemployment gap.
This introduction is divided into three parts. The first section examines the
principal trends and developments in the Canadian and American labour markets during
the past four decades. The second section reviews the factors that have been advanced to
explain the gap. Explanations are categorized into three main types -- measurement
issues, demand-side or cyclical explanations, and supply-side or structural explanations.
The third section summarizes the key findings of the 16 articles in this volume, and
discusses areas for further research and the policy implications of the findings.
I Comparative Labour Market Trends in Canada and the United States
An attempt to explain the emergence of the Canada-U.S. unemployment rate gap
should begin with an analysis of labour market trends in the two countries. The
unemployment rate cannot be analyzed in isolation of employment and labour force
developments since these influence the unemployment rate.
Unless otherwise specified, the data used in this section are from the Labour
Force Survey for Canada and the Current Population Survey for the United States. The
years used in the analysis are 1956, 1966, 1973, 1981 and 1989, which were business
cycle peaks in both countries, and 1996, the most recently available data. Thus the
periods 1956-66, 1966-73, 1973-81 and 1981-89 (but not necessarily 1989-96) are
reasonably free of cyclical influences.
Basic Labour Market Variables and Trends
Table 1
Basic Labour Market Trends in Canada and the United States, 1956-96
(average annual rate of change)
|
  |
WAP |
Part Rate |
LF |
Empl |
Empl/Pop |
UR |
Canada |
1956-66 |
1,9 |
0,7 |
2,6 |
2,6 |
0,7 |
0 |
1966-73 |
2,5 |
0,6 |
3,1 |
2,8 |
0,3 |
2,1 |
1973-81 |
2,1 |
1,1 |
3,3 |
2,9 |
0,9 |
2,1 |
1981-89 |
1,3 |
0,4 |
1,7 |
1,7 |
0,4 |
-0,1 |
1989-96 |
1,6 |
-0,6 |
1 |
0,6 |
-0,9 |
2,2 |
  |
United States |
1956-66 |
1,4 |
-0,1 |
1,3 |
1,3 |
-0,1 |
-0,3 |
1966-73 |
2 |
0,4 |
2,4 |
2,2 |
0,2 |
1,1 |
1973-81 |
1,8 |
0,6 |
2,5 |
2,1 |
0,3 |
2,2 |
1981-89 |
1,2 |
0,5 |
1,7 |
2 |
0,9 |
-2,3 |
1989-96 |
1,1 |
0,1 |
1,1 |
1,1 |
0 |
0,1 |
Notes: 1. WAP represents Working Age Population, Part Rate represents Labour Force
Participation Rate, LF represents Labour Force, Empl represents Employment, Empl/Pop
represents the Employment to Population ratio, and UR represents the Unemployment
Rate. All variables except UR are measured as average annual rates of change; the value
for UR is the change in the level over the period.
2. Some non-comparabilities and associated discontinuities occur in 1966 due to
changes in the underlying surveys.
Sources: Canada: 1956 data from Historical Statistics of Canada, second edition,
Statistics Canada, 1984, cat. 11-516; 1966 and 1973 data from Historical Labour Force
Statistics, Statistics Canada, February 1993, cat 71-201; post-1975 data from Labour
Force Historical Review, Statistics Canada, CD ROM version, February 1997.
United States: Economic Report of the President, February 1997.
Table 2
Participation Rate and Employment/Population Ratio in Canada and the United States
  |
Part Rate |
Empl/Pop |
Can |
US |
Can |
US |
1956 |
53,5 |
60 |
51,7 |
57,5 |
1966 |
57,3 |
59,2 |
55,4 |
56,9 |
  |
  |
  |
  |
  |
1973 |
59,7 |
60,8 |
56,4 |
57,8 |
  |
  |
  |
  |
  |
1981 |
65,3 |
63,9 |
60,4 |
59 |
1982 |
64,7 |
64 |
57,5 |
57,8 |
1983 |
64,9 |
64 |
57,1 |
57,9 |
1984 |
65,3 |
64,4 |
57,9 |
59,5 |
1985 |
65,8 |
64,8 |
58,9 |
60,1 |
1986 |
66,3 |
65,2 |
59,9 |
60,7 |
1987 |
66,7 |
65,6 |
60,8 |
61,5 |
1988 |
67,2 |
65,9 |
62 |
62,3 |
1989 |
67,5 |
66,4 |
62,4 |
62,9 |
  |
  |
  |
  |
  |
1990 |
67,3 |
66,5 |
61,9 |
62,8 |
1991 |
66,7 |
66,2 |
59,8 |
61,7 |
1992 |
65,9 |
66,4 |
58,4 |
61,5 |
1993 |
65,5 |
66,3 |
58,2 |
61,7 |
1994 |
65,3 |
66,6 |
58,5 |
62,5 |
1995 |
64,8 |
66,6 |
58,6 |
62,9 |
1996 |
64,9 |
66,8 |
58,6 |
63,2 |
Notes: 1. Part Rate and Empl/Pop represent the labour force participation rate and
employment/population ratio respectively.
2. Some non-comparabilities and associated discontinuities occur in 1966 due to
changes in the underlying surveys.
Sources: see Table 1
Working age population
Over the past four decades, growth in the working age population in Canada
(population 15 and over) exceeded that in the United States (defined as 16 and over)
because of faster overall population growth (Table 1). Because Canadian and American
birth rates are comparable, this faster population growth has primarily been due to
greater immigration to Canada. Both Canada and the United States experienced a
considerable fall off in the growth of the working age population beginning in the early
1980s as the last cohorts of the baby boom generation (those born in the first half of the
1960s) had by 1980 reached working age.
In the early 1980s, immigration to Canada fell off considerably, with the result
that the differential between Canadian and American population growth declined.
Immigration to Canada picked up in the second half of the 1980s and was very strong in
the first half of the 1990s (an average of 231 thousand immigrants over the 1990-96
period compared to 138 thousand in the 1985-89 period and only 114 thousand in the
1980-84 period). Consequently, in the 1990s, Canadian working age population growth
has exceeded U.S. growth by a larger margin (0.5 points) than was the case from the
1960s to the 1980s.
Labour force participation
In the 1950s, 1960s and 1970s, the labour force participation rate grew at a faster
rate in Canada than in the United States, with the result that by 1981 the Canadian
participation rate exceeded the American rate (Table 2). In the 1980s, the participation
rate in both countries continued to rise, although at a slightly faster rate in the United
States. In the 1990s, participation rate growth stagnated in the United States, and fell
sharply in Canada.
Labour force
In the 1950s, 1960s and 1970s, labour force growth was significantly higher in
Canada than in the United States (Table 1), reflecting the stronger growth in both the
working age population and participation. In the 1980s, labour force growth was
basically the same in the two countries, given the similar source population and
participation rate growth. In the 1990s, despite much stronger working age population
growth in Canada than in the United States, the falling Canadian participation rate has
produced labour force growth that is essentially the same in the two countries.
Employment
From the mid 1950s until the beginning of the 1980s, employment growth was
faster in Canada than in the United States (Table 1). This situation was reversed after
1981, with employment growth in the United States exceeding that in Canada by 0.3
percentage points per year in the 1981-89 period and by 0.5 points in the 1989-96 period.
Employment rate
The employment rate or employment-population ratio is determined by the
relative growth rates of the working age population and employment. During the decades
of the 1950s, 1960s and 1970s, this rate was lower in Canada than in the United States
and converged to the American level over the period (Table 2). By 1981, the Canadian
employment-population ratio exceeded the American ratio. In the 1980s and 1990s, the
Canadian ratio fell relative to the American ratio. It continued to advance in absolute
terms in the 1980s, but fell, precipitously, in the 1990s. The American rate has been
stable in the 1990s.
Table 3
Real Output and Productivity Growth in Canada and the United States, 1956-96
(average annual rate of change)
  |
Output |
Output Per Worker |
Canada |
US |
Canada |
US |
1956-66 |
4,7 |
3,8 |
2,1 |
2,5 |
1966-73 |
5,1 |
3,5 |
2,3 |
1,3 |
1973-81 |
3,8 |
2,4 |
0,9 |
0,3 |
1981-89 |
3,2 |
3,2 |
1,4 |
1,2 |
1989-96 |
1,2 |
1,9 |
0,6 |
0,8 |
Sources: Output: Canada - Economic Reference Tables, Department of Finance, August
1996; U.S. - 1956-66 calculated from Table B-2, Economic Report of the President,
February 1991; other years from Economic Report of the President, February 1997.
Output per worker growth rates calculated residually from output growth and
employment growth rates in Table 1.
Output
From the mid-1950s to the beginning of the 1980s, Canada enjoyed considerably
faster real output growth than the United States (Table 3). This situation changed
drastically after 1981. In the 1980s, the growth rates of the two economies were roughly
comparable, while in the 1989-96 period, the United States outperformed Canada by an
average 0.7 percentage points per year.
Output per worker
In the 1966-81 period, and to somewhat lesser extent in the 1981-89 period,
Canada enjoyed higher productivity growth than did the U.S. Since 1989, growth in
output per worker has been slightly higher (0.2 percentage points per year) in the United
States.
Unemployment rate
Although the behavior of unemployment in Canada and the United States was
very similar during the 1945-1980 period, some divergence did occur (Table 4). A
modest positive Canada-U.S. unemployment rate gap emerged in the decade of the 1960s
(0.2 percentage points), after a situation of lower unemployment in Canada in the late
1940s and 1950s. The gap widened slightly to an average 0.5 percentage points in the
1970s -- a decade with years when unemployment was much lower in Canada than in the
United States (e.g. 1.6 points in 1975) and years when unemployment was much higher
in Canada (e.g. 2.2 points in 1978). Average unemployment rates over cyclically neutral
periods were also modestly higher in Canada from the mid-1950s to the beginning of the
1980s.
In the 1980s, the Canada-U.S. unemployment rate gap jumped to an average 2.1
points and then to 3.9 points in the 1990s. Since 1992, the gap has been 4 percentage
points or over. In 1996, the gap was 4.3 points, based on a Canadian unemployment rate
of 9.7 per cent and an American rate of 5.4 per cent.
Since the mid-1950s, in only seven out of 40 years was the Canadian
unemployment rate below the American rate. This occurred in the four-year 1963-66
period and in the three-year 1974-76 period. In both periods, and particularly in the
second period, economic growth was stronger in Canada.(1)
In 1981, a cyclical peak year, the unemployment rate was 7.6 per cent in both
countries. By 1989, at the peak of the 1981-89 business cycle, it had fallen to 5.3 per cent
in the United States, but remained virtually unchanged at 7.5 per cent in Canada. Thus,
the Canada-U.S. unemployment rate gap rose 2.2 percentage points between 1981 and
1989. By 1996, the unemployment rate had increased to 9.7 per cent in Canada,
compared to only 5.4 per cent in the United States. Consequently, the gap in the 1990s
rose an additional 2.1 points from that in 1989, reaching 4.3 points.
Canada experienced severe recessions in 1981-82 and 1990-92, the first times in
Canadian economic history that recessions had been deeper than in the United States.
These recessions triggered an increase in the unemployment gap in both the early 1980s
and early 1990s, and the gap was not eliminated in the subsequent recovery and
expansion. From this perspective, there are really two unemployment differentials - the
approximately 2 percentage point gap of the 1980s and the additional 2 percentage point
gap of the 1990s superimposed on the differential which emerged in the 1980s.
Table 4
The Unemployment Rate in Canada and the United States, 1956-96
(per cent)
  |
Canada |
United States |
Canada-U.S. gap |
1956 |
3,4 |
4,1 |
-0,7 |
1966 |
3,4 |
3,8 |
-0,4 |
1973 |
5,5 |
4,9 |
0,6 |
1981 |
7,6 |
7,6 |
0 |
1982 |
11 |
9,7 |
1,3 |
1983 |
11,9 |
9,6 |
2,3 |
1984 |
11,3 |
7,5 |
3,8 |
1985 |
10,5 |
7,2 |
3,3 |
1986 |
9,6 |
7 |
2,6 |
1987 |
8,9 |
6,2 |
2,7 |
1988 |
7,8 |
5,5 |
2,3 |
1989 |
7,5 |
5,3 |
2,2 |
1990 |
8,1 |
5,5 |
2,6 |
1991 |
10,4 |
6,7 |
3,7 |
1992 |
11,3 |
7,4 |
3,9 |
1993 |
11,2 |
6,8 |
4,4 |
1994 |
10,4 |
6,1 |
4,3 |
1995 |
9,6 |
5,6 |
4 |
1996 |
9,7 |
5,4 |
4,3 |
  |
  |
Decade averages |
1950-59 |
4,2 |
4,5 |
-0,3 |
1960-69 |
5 |
4,8 |
0,2 |
1970-79 |
6,7 |
6,2 |
0,5 |
1980-89 |
9,4 |
7,3 |
2,1 |
1990-96 |
10,1 |
6,2 |
3,9 |
  |
  |
Averages over 'cyclically neutral' periods |
1956-65 |
5,7 |
5,4 |
0,3 |
1966-73 |
5 |
4,5 |
0,5 |
1974-81 |
7,3 |
6,9 |
0,4 |
1982-89 |
9,8 |
7,3 |
2,5 |
Sources: See Table 1.
Divergent Labour Market Developments Between the 1980s and 1990s
The labour market dynamics behind the emergence of a sustained Canada-U.S.
unemployment rate gap in the 1980s and the increase in the gap in the 1990s appear to
fundamentally differ. Between the 1981 and 1989 cyclical peaks, the Canadian labour
market, on average, performed well. The weak labour market conditions at the early part
of the decade associated with the 1981-82 recession were offset by the strong expansion
following the recession. The participation rate continued to climb as did the
employment-population ratio. Both employment growth and labour force growth were
relatively strong (1.7 per cent per year), resulting in no change in the unemployment rate
between 1981 and 1989.
During the 1981-89 period, the United States experienced slightly more rapid
growth of participation and a modestly greater increase in the employment-population
ratio than did Canada. Employment growth was also faster in the United States than in
Canada (2.0 versus 1.7 percent per year), and U.S. employment growth exceeded labour
force growth (1.7 per cent per year), resulting in a 2.3 percentage point fall in the
American unemployment rate between 1981 and 1989. Thus the emergence of a
sustained Canada-U.S. unemployment rate in the 1980s reflected the superior
performance (at least in terms of employment and unemployment outcomes) of the
American economy, not an absolute deterioration of labour market performance in
Canada. Furthermore, the inter-country differences in employment performance were
modest; between 1981 and 1989, the employment rate increased by 2.0 percentage points
in Canada versus 2.9 points in the United States (Table 2).
The situation in the 1990s is markedly different. Between 1989 and 1996, the
performance of the Canadian economy deteriorated severely. Both the participation rate
and the employment-population ratio dropped significantly and employment growth was
very weak (0.6 per cent per year), well below that of labour force growth (1.0 per cent).
Consequently, the unemployment rate rose 2.2 points between 1989 and 1996.
The performance of the American economy in the 1990s also deteriorated from
that of the 1980s, but the deterioration was not as severe as in Canada. The participation
rate and the employment rate were basically unchanged between 1989 and 1996 (in
contrast to increases in the 1980s). Employment and labour force growth were down
from that experienced in the 1980s and the unemployment rate in 1996 was also
unchanged from what it had been in 1989. Thus the increase in the Canada-U.S.
unemployment rate gap after 1989 reflects the very poor performance of the Canadian
labour market, poor in an absolute sense and relative to that of the American labour
market.
Canada's much weaker labour market in the 1990s largely reflected the weaker
economic growth performance. Real GDP advanced at only a 1.2 per cent average
annual rate between 1989 and 1996 in Canada, compared to 1.9 per cent in the United
States. In contrast, during the 1980s output growth was the same in the two countries (3.2
per cent per year).
The cumulative impact on unemployment of this divergence in growth rates over
a seven-year period is substantial. In Canada, in the 1990s, output growth has been
composed of two roughly equal components, employment growth and productivity
growth. This implies that if output growth had been 0.7 percentage points per year
stronger in the 1990s (that is, equal to that experienced in the United States), and if the
50-50 division into employment and productivity growth were maintained, employment
growth would have been 0.35 percentage points per year stronger, or 2.5 per cent higher
over a seven year period. Assuming no effect of stronger employment growth on the size
of the labour force, the unemployment rate would have been approximately 2.5 points
lower in 1996 than in 1989. Thus, in an arithmetic sense, the gap between American and
Canadian economic growth rates since 1989 accounts for the further widening of the
unemployment differential in the 1990s.
The Nature of Unemployment in Canada and the United States
Supplementary measures of labour force under-utilization
To fully understand developments in the Canadian and American labour markets,
it is useful to examine trends in the relative size of groups who are excluded from the
officially unemployed, but who nevertheless may represent underutilized labour. For
example, a simple explanation of the emergence of the unemployment differential in the
1980s (or the further widening of the gap in the 1990s) would be that there was an
increased tendency in the U.S. (or a reduced tendency in Canada) for under-utilization of
labour to take forms other than those captured by the conventional unemployment rate.
Two key groups in this regard are discouraged workers and involuntary part-time
workers.
Discouraged workers are defined in similar albeit not identical ways in the U.S.
and Canada. They consist of individuals who are not employed in the survey week, did
not search for work during the past four weeks, but who are available for work and who
state that they want work. In addition, discouraged workers must give as their main
reason for not searching "believes no work is available" (in both the LFS and CPS) or
"could not find any work", "lacks necessary schooling, training, skills or experience",
"employers think too young or too old", "other personal handicaps in finding a job (such
as discrimination or criminal record)" (in the CPS). Thus the main difference in the
measurement of discouragement in the two countries is that the United States allows a
broader set of reasons for not looking for work.
Discouraged workers represented almost identical shares of the labour force in
Canada and the United States in both 1983 and 1993, for both men and women, with
their relative importance falling between 1983 and 1993 (see Table 5).(2) Thus inclusion
of discouraged workers among the unemployed in 1983 or 1993 would not change the
absolute size of the Canada-U.S. unemployment rate gap.(3)
Another dimension of under-employment is involuntary part-time work. Two
such measures are available. One (denoted by Invol. PT (workers) in Table 5) refers to
those who are working part time because they couldn't find full time work. The
evidence reported in Table 5 suggests that this type of under-employment may be more
prevalent in Canada than in the United States. Unfortunately, differences in the
definition of part time employment during this period (30 hours or less per week in
Canada versus 35 hours or less per week in the U.S.) make the inter-country comparison
problematic. However, it is clear that there was an increase in this form of under-employment in Canada between 1983 and 1993, versus a decrease in the U.S.
Invol. PT (hours) refers to those laid off part of the week or working reduced
hours for "economic" reasons. The data in Table 5 suggest that this form of under-utilization of labour may be more prevalent in the United States; however, the
differences in the definition of part time employment again make it difficult to compare
the two countries. In this case the intertemporal comparison is also problematic because
this 'reduced hours' measure was not available in Canada prior to 1989. The U.S. data,
however, does indicate a slight decline in this form of involuntary part time work
between 1983 and 1993.
In summary, the extent of under-utilization of labour not captured in the
conventional unemployment rate appears to have declined in the United States; all three
measures reported in Table 5 fell between 1983 and 1993. In contrast, in Canada the
various measures do not all move in the same direction; the number of discouraged
workers fell but the amount of involuntary part time employment rose. While inter-country comparisons cannot be made with confidence because of measurement
differences, the widening of the unemployment differential in the 1990s appears also to
have been accompanied by an increased Canada-U.S. difference in other forms of labour
market slack. Thus it would be difficult to argue on the basis of this evidence that the
widening of the unemployment gap is due to an increased tendency in the U.S. (or a
decreased tendency in Canada) for under-utilization of labour to take forms other than
those captured by the conventional unemployment rate.
Another perspective on the under-utilization of labour can be obtained by looking
as the relative participation rate movement in the two countries. As noted earlier, in the
1980s the aggregate participation rate rose in both countries. But in the 1990s, while the
participation rate continued to rise in the United States, albeit at a much slower rate, it
fell in Canada, going from a peak of 67.5 per cent in 1989 to 64.9 per cent in 1996. The
decline in participation was greatest for youth and older males. The factors behind this
unprecedented decline in labour force participation are unclear, but the magnitude of the
decline in Canada relative to the U.S. suggests that the increase in the unemployment rate
differential in the 1990s may understate the relative growth of labour market slack in
Canada.
Table 5
Supplementary Measures of Labour Market Slack in Canada and the U.S., 1983 and
1993
  |
1983 |
1993 |
Can |
U.S. |
Can-U.S. |
Can |
U.S. |
Can-U.S. |
both sexes |
Unemployment rate |
12 |
9,8 |
2,2 |
11,3 |
6,9 |
4,4 |
Discouraged workers |
1,6 |
1,5 |
0,1 |
0,9 |
0,9 |
0 |
Invol. PT (workers) |
3,9 |
2,9 |
1 |
5,5 |
2,2 |
3,3 |
Invol. PT (hours) |
0,8* |
2,9 |
-2,1 |
1 |
2,8 |
-1,8 |
  |
men |
Unemployment rate |
12,2 |
10,1 |
2,1 |
11,8 |
7,2 |
4,6 |
Discouraged workers |
1,2 |
1,1 |
0,1 |
0,8 |
0,8 |
0 |
Invol. PT (workers) |
2,1 |
1,9 |
0,2 |
3,3 |
1,6 |
1,7 |
Invol. PT (hours) |
0,8* |
2,9 |
-2,1 |
1,1 |
2,9 |
-1,8 |
  |
women |
Unemployment rate |
11,7 |
9,3 |
2,4 |
10,7 |
6,6 |
4,1 |
Discouraged workers |
2,2 |
2 |
0,2 |
1 |
1 |
0 |
Invol. PT (workers) |
6,5 |
4,1 |
2,5 |
8,2 |
3,1 |
5,1 |
Invol. PT (hours) |
0,8* |
2,8 |
-2 |
0,9 |
2,6 |
-1,7 |
Source: OECD Employment Outlook, July 1995
Notes: * denotes 1989 data
The unemployment rate gap by labour force characteristics
Further insight into the factors behind the Canada-U.S. unemployment rate gap
can be obtained by disaggregating changes in unemployment to ascertain whether the
post-1981 unemployment rate gap is a general phenomenon, or rather is confined to
certain groups. This section, based on Sharpe (1996), summarizes unemployment in
Canada and the United States by gender, region, occupation, industry, and educational
attainment.
In the 1980s, the gap emerged from a fall in the unemployment rate in the United
States. In the 1990s, the gap was increased by the rise in the unemployment rate in
Canada. It is instructive to see how widespread these general developments are among
the various labour force groups.
- Both the male and female unemployment rates fell significantly in the United States
in the 1980s equally contributing to the emergence of the gap. While both rates rose
in Canada in the 1990s, the male unemployment rate increased more and thus
contributed more to the rise in the gap.(4)
- The rise in the Canada-U.S. unemployment rate gap affected all age groups in both
the 1980s and 1990s. In the 1980s the emergence of the gap was roughly equally
apportioned across all major age groups, while the increase in the 1990s was
disproportionately large for youth.(5)
- The large regional changes in unemployment rates in Canada meant that the
contributions by region to the gap in the 1980s and 1990s differed markedly. Between
1981 and 1989, the rise in the Canada-U.S. unemployment rate gap had been driven
by the rise of unemployment in the Prairies and in British Columbia (Table A1). In
contrast, the rise in the gap between 1989 and 1996 was driven by Ontario. However,
the variations in relative regional unemployment rates within the 1981-96 period
were somewhat offsetting and all five regions experienced major increases in the
differential between their unemployment rate and the U.S. rate (5.3 points in the
Prairies, 4.6 points in Atlantic Canada, 4.7 points in Ontario, 4.4 points in British
Columbia, and 3.6 points in Quebec).
- The unemployment rate for workers in all major industries in the United States fell in
the 1980s, while that for workers in the vast majority of industries rose in Canada in
the 1990s. The gap has been consistently and significantly higher in the goods sector
than in the service sector.
- The fall in unemployment in the 1980s in the United States was experienced by all
occupations, as was the rise in unemployment in Canada in the 1990s. Thus the rise
in the Canada-U.S. unemployment rate gap was a phenomenon that affected all
occupations.
- The decline in unemployment in the United States in the 1980s was experienced
across the educational attainment spectrum, as was the rise in unemployment rates in
Canada in the 1990s.
Unemployment duration and incidence
The total number of weeks of unemployment experienced in a year is determined
by both the average duration of unemployment and the proportion of the labour force
that experience a bout of unemployment or the incidence of unemployment.
Decomposing total unemployment into incidence and duration components may provide
insights into the factors underlying changes in unemployment.
There are a number of ways to calculate the duration of unemployment. The
simplest approach, and the one what will be followed here, is to look at the average
unemployment duration for those currently unemployed, data which is readily available
from the household labour force surveys. These unemployment spells are incomplete (in
progress), and the decomposition of total unemployment into duration and incidence
components based on this "interrupted spell" measure of duration is only an
approximation. The papers by Baker, Corak, and Heisz and Tille in the volume use more
sophisticated approaches, namely the average duration of a completed spell of
unemployment and the average number of weeks spent in unemployment during the year
by individuals experiencing some unemployment. All three approaches give consistent
results.
According to LFS and CPS data on uncompleted duration of unemployment, in
the 1980s the fall in the unemployment rate in the United States was primarily due to a
fall in the incidence of unemployment (from 28.9 per cent of the labour force to 23.0 per
cent), although a fall in the duration of unemployment also contributed. The
unemployment rate in Canada was essentially unchanged between 1981 and 1989,
reflecting offsetting tendencies from a rise in the average duration of unemployment
from 15.1 to 17.9 weeks (Table A2) and a fall in the incidence from 26.0 to 21.9 per cent
of the labour force.
In the 1990s, the rise in the unemployment rate in Canada was again accounted
for by a rise in unemployment duration (from 18 weeks in 1989 to 24 weeks in 1996),
with the incidence of unemployment actually lower in 1996 than 1989 (21 per cent
versus 22 per cent). Indeed, the average duration of unemployment in 1996 was well
above that experienced in the early 1980s (e.g. 22 weeks in 1983) when the
unemployment rate was higher. In the United States, the unchanged unemployment rate
between 1989 and 1996 was associated with an increase in duration (from 12 to 17
weeks) and a very steep fall in incidence (23 to 17 per cent of the labour force). Thus in
both countries unemployment became more concentrated among a smaller subset of the
labour force during the 1980s and 1990s.(6) This decline in the incidence of
unemployment occurred to a similar extent in both Canada and the United States during
the 1980s, but occurred to a much greater extent in the U.S. during the 1990s.
The rise in the average duration of unemployment in both countries in the 1990s
meant that the relative importance of long-term unemployment in total unemployment
increased significantly. In Canada, the proportion of the unemployed without work for 27
weeks or more increased from 20.1 per cent in 1989 to 27.1 per cent in 1996, while in the
United States this proportion increased from 9.9 per cent in 1989 to 17.4 per cent in 1996
(Table A3). Given the roughly comparable rises in the duration of unemployment in the
two countries, the increased Canada-U.S. gap in the 1990s principally reflected the much
greater fall in the incidence of unemployment in the United States.
Job turnover
Net changes in employment between two periods of time reflect the outcome of
gross job gains (due to opening and expansions) and gross job losses (due to closures and
contractions). The aggregation of job gains and losses gives labour turnover. Data from
the OECD Jobs Study for the United States and Canada on job losses and gains is
presented in Table A4.
In the 1980s, when the net change in employment was very similar in the two
countries, the magnitude of gross job gains and job losses was also very close, although
expansions and contractions were more important in Canada and openings and closures
in the United States. Between 1989 and 1991, when employment fell in Canada, but
continued to expand in the United States, gross job losses were much larger in Canada,
but gross job gains were also larger despite the recession. Falling employment in Canada
earlier in the 1990s was due to increased job losses, not a falloff in the pace of job gains.
Baldwin, Dunne and Haltiwanger (1994) found little qualitative difference in job
creation in manufacturing between Canada and the United States over the 1973-86
period, nor did they find any major structural differences in job turnover patterns
between the two countries.
Summary
The main points that emerge from this examination of comparative labour market
behavior in Canada and the United States are:
1. The dynamics behind the development of the inter-country unemployment
differential in the 1980s and 1990s differ. In the 1980s, the emergence of a sustained
2 percentage point unemployment rate gap occurred during a period in which overall
economic growth in the two countries was identical. Both countries experienced
rising employment and participation rates during this decade (although employment
growth in Canada was modestly lower than in the U.S.). It is difficult, therefore, to
argue that the emergence of the unemployment gap can be explained by differences in
the macroeconomic performances of the two countries. In contrast, in the 1990s,
Canadian macroeconomic performance was much weaker than that of the United
States. Accompanying this weaker economic growth, Canada's unemployment rate
rose and employment and labour force participation rates declined relative to their
U.S. counterparts. The further widening of the unemployment differential during the
1990s appears consistent with a simple explanation in terms of differential
macroeconomic performance between the two countries.
2.The widening of the unemployment gap in the 1990s appears also to have been
accompanied by an increased Canada - U.S. differential in other forms of under-utilization of labour such as involuntary part time employment.
3. The emergence of the inter-country unemployment differential has been a
pervasive phenomenon, affecting both men and women, all regions, all age groups, all
industries and occupations, and all educational attainment groups.
4. In both countries, unemployment became more concentrated among a smaller
subset of the labour force during the 1980s and 1990s. This decline in the incidence
of unemployment occurred to a similar extent in both countries during the 1980s, but
occurred to a greater extent in the U.S. during the 1990s. The average duration of
unemployment increased in both countries over the 1981-96 period, albeit the increase
was somewhat larger in Canada.
5. The behavior of gross job creation and gross job destruction was similar in the
two countries during the 1980s. In the 1989-91 period, both job creation and job
destruction were higher in Canada than in the United States, but in Canada gross job
destruction exceeded gross job creation whereas the opposite was true in the U.S.
II Explanations of the Canada-U.S. Unemployment Rate Gap
This section provides a framework for the papers that follow. Explanations of the
gap are divided into three basic types- differences in the measurement of unemployment
in Canada and the United States, macroeconomic or aggregate demand explanations and
structural factors.
Statistical Measurement Issues
Examining the measurement of labour force activities is a logical way to begin
the search for explanations of inter-country differences in unemployment. If such
concepts as the labour force, employment and the unemployment are not defined and
measured in the same manner in Canada and the United States, then the respective
unemployment rates are not comparable. Changes in measurement practices over time
can also affect movements in the gap. Canada and the United States employ household
surveys (the Labour Force Survey (LFS) and the Current Population Survey (CPS)
respectively) to measure labour market activities.
Difference in treatment of "passive" job searchers
Until recently, it was believed that there were no significant differences in the
manner in which unemployment is measured in Canada and the United States. Indeed,
the standardized unemployment rate estimates produced by the OECD and the U.S.
Bureau of Labor Statistics show virtually no difference between the standardized and
national rates. Recent research has, however, changed this view.
In a detailed examination of the Labour Force Survey and Current Population
Survey questionnaires, Zagorsky (1996) found that persons not employed who responded
that their only job search method was looking at job ads in newspapers were classified as
in the labour force and unemployed in Canada while they were treated as out of the
labour force in the United States. Macredie (1996) produced estimates for the 1976-93
period of the number of unemployed persons in Canada whose only job search method
was "looked at ads" in order to obtain information on the magnitude of the contribution
of these definitional differences to measured unemployment.
In 1993, 114 thousand unemployed persons looked at job ads only. When these
persons are excluded from the labour force, the Canadian unemployment rate falls 0.7
percentage points, reducing the gap with the U.S. rate by 17 per cent. Moreover, for
reasons that are unclear, the size of this group has increased significantly over time. In
1981, excluding these so-called "passive" job searchers would have reduced the
measured unemployment rate by only 0.4 percentage points. Thus 0.3 percentage points
of the increase in Canada-U.S. unemployment rate gap between 1981 and 1993 is due to
this definitional difference in the measurement of unemployment.(7)
Redesign of the CPS in 1994
Beginning in January 1994, a revised Current Population Survey was introduced
in the United States. This represented the first major redesign in the CPS since 1967.
Both the old and revised surveys were run in parallel for 18 months before the formal
introduction of the new survey. The unemployment rate as measured by the new survey
averaged a half a percentage point higher than estimates from the old CPS. In addition,
the use of new population estimates increased the measured unemployment rate another
0.1 percentage point (Council of Economic Advisors, 1994:104). The unemployment rate
was higher for all demographic groups, but particularly for women since the old CPS
survey may have tended to classify women who were unemployed as outside the labour
force. This suggests that in 1994 the U.S. unemployment rate under the old CPS would
have been 5.5 per cent instead of the actually measured 6.1 per cent. If so, the Canada-U.S. unemployment gap in 1994 would have been 4.9 points, instead of the actually
measured 4.3 points.
Unfortunately, it is impossible to say whether the 0.6 percentage point difference
between the old and revised CPS which the 1992-93 parallel surveys found has
continued. This makes it difficult to say whether the post-1993 estimates of the Canada-U.S. unemployment rate gap have a downward bias - and, if so, the magnitude of this
bias - associated with the introduction of the redesigned CPS.
Aggregate Demand Explanations
As discussed previously, both the 1981-82 and 1990-92 recessions were
significantly more severe - as measured for example by the decline in total output
relative to trend growth in output -- in Canada than in the United States. This
observation raises the question of whether the unemployment differential may have a
simple cyclical or 'deficient demand' explanation. The timing of the unemployment gap
-- its emergence in the early 1980s and the further widening in the early 1990s - appears
to accord with this view. This section examines some evidence relating to this cyclical
explanation.
Estimates of the NAIRU
A commonly employed method for distinguishing the effects of the business cycle
from those associated with longer term trends and structural factors is to decompose total
unemployment into cyclical and frictional/structural unemployment. Cyclical or demand-deficient unemployment is generally defined as the difference between actual
unemployment and the non-accelerating-inflation rate of unemployment (NAIRU) while
the NAIRU is in turn defined as the sum of frictional and structural unemployment.
Despite the attraction of this approach, it should be noted that the breakdown of
unemployment into frictional/structural and cyclical components may not be
conceptually valid.(8) Furthermore, even if the conceptual distinction is accepted,
estimates of the NAIRU are very sensitive to the methodology and procedures used in
their estimation (Setterfield, Gordon and Osberg, 1992; Staiger, Stock and Watson, 1997)
and therefore should be interpreted with considerable caution.
There is no consensus on the size of the NAIRU for Canada. According to a
recent survey, estimates of the NAIRU in Canada range from a high of 9.5 per cent to a
low of 6.5 per cent, with the average estimate being 7.7 per cent (OECD,1996:159).
Estimates of the relative importance of demand-deficient unemployment vary
accordingly.
For the United States, the conventional wisdom has been that the NAIRU in the
mid-1990s was around 6.0 per cent. But the fall in unemployment in the United States (in
the second and third quarters of 1997 the US unemployment rate averaged 4.9 per cent)
and the absence of an acceleration of inflation, suggests that the NAIRU is below this
level. Robert Gordon (1996), for example, estimates a time-varying NAIRU of 5.5 per
cent in 1996.
Based on the average NAIRU estimate for Canada of 7.7 per cent from the OECD
survey, 2 percentage points of Canada's 9.7 per cent unemployment rate in 1996 can be
attributed to cyclical factors. The actual unemployment rate in the United States in 1996
was virtually identical to the estimated NAIRU, suggesting the absence of demand-deficient unemployment.
In terms of the 4.1 percentage points Canada-U.S. unemployment rate gap in
1996, the average NAIRU estimate suggests 2.0 percentage points or one half can be
explained by cyclical factors and 2.1 percentage points by other factors, including
structural factors as manifested in the higher Canadian NAIRU. However, this
calculation should be treated very cautiously because of the considerable uncertainty
surrounding estimates of the NAIRU.
Table 6
Canadian and American Total Economy Output Gaps
(actual-potential GDP)
  |
Original OECD Series |
OECD Revised Series |
Canada |
U.S. |
Can-U.S. |
Canada |
U.S. |
Can-U.S. |
1981 |
0,26 |
-1,91 |
2,17 |
0,37 |
-1,11 |
1,48 |
1989 |
0,14 |
2,17 |
-2,03 |
3,64 |
2,09 |
1,55 |
1994 |
-9,33 |
1,03 |
-10,36 |
-1,95 |
0,25 |
-2,2 |
1996 |
na |
na |
na |
-2,65 |
-0,31 |
-2,34 |
Source: original series from OECD Interlink Model for Economic Outlook 53, December
1993; revised series, OECD August 1997
Trends in output gaps
Another method often used to assess the importance of cyclical factors uses the
estimated output gap, the difference between actual and (estimated) potential output.
This method is closely related to that based on decomposing unemployment, and suffers
from the same difficulties - the conceptual issue of whether it is in fact meaningful to
distinguish between cyclical and structural movements and the practical issue of
obtaining convincing estimates of potential output.
An analysis of trends in the output gap provides support for the view that
differences in cyclical developments in the two countries may account for the further
widening of the Canada-U.S. unemployment differential after 1989. According to OECD
estimates, the Canadian economy was operating 2.7 per cent below capacity in 1996, a
deterioration of 6.3 points from 3.6 per cent above potential in 1989. In contrast, the
American economy was operating 0.3 per cent below capacity, down 2.4 points from 2.1
above potential in 1989. The larger increase in the Canadian output gap relative to that of
the American economy (3.9 points) over the 1989-96 period was associated with a 2.1
point increase in the unemployment rate gap.(9)
The evidence for a cyclical explanation of
the gap in the 1980s is mixed and depends on which potential output series is used.(10)
Structural Factors
Structural explanations are a diverse category and are best defined as those that
could account for the unemployment differential despite identical measurement
procedures and macroeconomic conditions in the two countries. Included are a large
number of institutional, behavioral, demographic, and economic factors. This section
looks at a number of these factors, including labour force attachment, unemployment
insurance, unionization, structural change, taxes, wages, and demographic characteristics
including immigration and the size of the incarcerated population.
Although these various "structural explanations" are discussed separately, it is
important to keep in mind that they are inter-related. For example, institutional features
such as the degree of unionization or the features of income support programs are likely
to influence such dimensions as wage adjustment and the adaptability of the economy to
structural change. Thus headings in what follows such as "wage trends" and "structural
change" are not necessarily independent of other aspects such as "unionization" and
"unemployment insurance".
Labour force attachment of the non-employed
In their analysis of Canada - United States unemployment, Card and Riddell
(1993) found that the emergence of the unemployment gap in the 1980s was associated
with a change in how Canadians spend their time when not employed relative to
Americans. Specifically, relative to the period before the emergence of the
unemployment differential, during the 1980s Canadians became more likely than
Americans to spend their non-employment time searching for work (and therefore
classified as unemployed) rather than not looking for work (and therefore classified as
out-of-the-labour force). This change in the degree of "labour force attachment" of non-employed Canadians relative to non-employed Americans (11)accounts for 80 to 90 percent
of the 2 percentage point unemployment gap that opened up in the 1980s, with the
remaining 10-20 percent being accounted for by other factors such as changes in labour
force participation and employment rates.(12)
This finding has two principal implications. First, it explains the emergence of a
substantial inter-country unemployment gap during a period in which overall economic
growth and employment growth were similar in the two countries. Second, it implies
that understanding the cause(s) of the unemployment gap that emerged in the 1980s
requires understanding the factors that led to the increase in labour force attachment of
the non-employed in Canada relative to the U.S.
As discussed in the previous section, the factors underlying the further widening
of the unemployment gap in the 1990s appear to differ from those which led to the initial
emergence of the gap in the 1980s. In order to examine the role of the labour force
attachment of the non-employed - that is, how the non-employed divide their time
between searching for work and not searching - we update some of the analysis in Card
and Riddell (1993). The conventional unemployment rate, which is the probability of
unemployment conditional on being in the labour force, can be expressed as
P(U|LF) = P(U|N) * P(N) / P(LF)
where P(LF) is the probability of being in the labour force (the labour force participation
rate), P(N) is the probability of non-employment (one minus the employment rate), and
P(U|N) is the probability of unemployment conditional on being non-employed (the
labour force attachment of the non-employed). Thus the logarithm of the unemployment
rate is
ln P(U|LF) = ln P(N) + ln P(U|N) - ln P(LF)
This expression allows changes in the unemployment rate to be decomposed into three
components: changes in labour force participation, in non-employment, and in the labour
force attachment of the non-employed. Table 6 reports decompositions of difference-in-differences in the logarithm of the unemployment rate for the 1980s (1981 to 1989), the
1990s (1989 to 1996) and the entire period 1981-96. Applying this decomposition to the
1980s shows that 85% of the relative increase in Canada's unemployment rate was
associated with the rise in labour force attachment of the non-employed in Canada
relative to the U.S. Most of the remainder (14%) was due to the modestly superior
employment performance in the U.S. (see Tables 1 and 2). Relative changes in labour
force participation were not a contributing factor to the emergence of the unemployment
gap during the 1980s.
Another way to express this result is as follows. Suppose that in both countries
the source population, employment and labour force participation rate evolved as they in
fact did over the 1981-89 period. Suppose further that in the United States the labour
force attachment of the non-employed evolved as it in fact did, but that in Canada P(U|N)
evolved such that no relative change in P(U|N) between Canada and the U.S. occurred.
In these circumstances, the 1989 unemployment rates in the U.S. and Canada would have
been 5.3 (the actual rate) and 5.6 percent respectively. The difference between this latter
simulated [under the assumption of no relative change in P(U|N)] unemployment rate of
5.6 percent and the actual rate in 1989 of 7.5 percent, a difference of 1.9 percentage
points, is the amount due to the rise in the labour force attachment of the non-employed
in Canada relative to the U.S. This difference of 1.9 percentage points is 85 per cent of
the difference-in-differences of Canadian and American unemployment rates between
1981 and 1989, which totals 2.2 percentage points (i.e. the Canadian difference of [7.5-7.6] - the U.S. difference of [5.3-7.6], which equals 2.2).
The story in the 1990s is dramatically different. The relative increase in non-employment in Canada is the most important factor, contributing 44 per cent of the
widening of the unemployment differential in the 1990s, and the relative change in
participation now contributes 19 per cent. Relative changes in the labour force
attachment of the non-employed nonetheless remain a contributing factor, accounting for
37 per cent of the widening of the unemployment gap.
In interpreting these results, it is important to keep in mind that the first
difference-in-differences comparison involves two points in time (1981 and 1989) which
were cyclical peaks in both countries, while the second is not cyclically neutral in this
sense. In 1996 the Canadian economy had not recovered from the recession of the early
1990s to the same degree as that of the U.S. Because the non-employment rate, the
labour force participation rate and P(U|N) are each affected by the business cycle, the
decomposition for 1989-96 does not necessarily represent the contributions of structural
factors.
Over the entire 1981-1996 period, the most important factor contributing to the
unemployment differential is the relative increase in P(U|N) in Canada, accounting for 65
per cent of the gap. The relative decline in Canada's employment to population ratio
accounts for a further 26 per cent, and relative changes in participation are a minor
factor, accounting for only 9 per cent of the gap.
Table 7
Decomposition of the Relative Change in Unemployment
Time period |
Relative change in unemployment |
Amount contributed by the relative change of |
P(N) |
P(U|N) |
P(LF) |
1981-1989 |
34,7 |
4,8 |
29,4 |
0,5 |
(100%) |
(14%) |
(85%) |
(1%) |
1989-1996 |
23,9 |
10,4 |
8,8 |
4,5 |
(100%) |
(44%) |
(37%) |
(19%) |
1981-1996 |
58,6 |
15,3 |
38,1 |
5,1 |
(100%) |
(26%) |
(65%) |
(9%) |
Sources: Participation rates and employment rates as per Table 2; unemployment rates as
per Table 4, and calculations by the authors.
Unemployment insurance
Canada's Unemployment Insurance (UI) system (now called Employment
Insurance) is frequently signaled out as a factor in the rise of unemployment in Canada
relative to the United States (e.g. Moorthy, 1989/90; Keil and Symons, 1990; Card and
Riddell, 1993; M. Fortin,1994, among others). Although the complexity of UI benefit and
financing provisions make cross-country comparisons difficult, a variety of measures
indicate that the Canadian UI system has been more generous than the American system,
and that these inter-country differences widened during the 1970s and 1980s.(13)
Much of the Canadian debate has focused on the impact of the 1971 UI reforms
on the unemployment rate. In Canada, UI generosity increased dramatically in 1971 but
has since been constant or declining (see, e.g., OECD, 1994; Sargent, 1995). But a
sustained Canada-U.S. unemployment rate gap emerged in the 1980s, not the 1970s.
Thus the timing of the emergence of the unemployment gap does not seem to fit well
with the UI explanation.
Despite this apparent difficulty, a number of reasons why UI may have been a
contributing factor have been advanced. One simple observation is that what matters for
the explanation of the unemployment gap is the inter-country differential in UI program
features. Generosity of both the Canadian and American UI programs increased during
the 1970s (OECD, 1994); although the increase was larger in Canada, the inter-country
difference in UI generosity did not grow as much as is indicated from inspection of the
Canadian changes alone. Furthermore, during the 1980s UI benefit entitlements (after
tax) were reduced and eligibility requirements were tightened in the United States,
whereas these and other features of the UI program remained approximately constant in
Canada.(14) Andolfatto, Gomme and Storer (this volume) examine some of the changes
made to the U.S. unemployment insurance program during the 1980s, and present
evidence suggesting that these may have been an important factor contributing to the
unemployment gap.
It is also possible that the dramatic expansion of the Canadian UI program in the
early 1970s did lead to an increase in structural unemployment, but that this did not
immediately result in a higher actual unemployment rate because of the very robust
economy of the period caused by high raw material and energy prices and expansionary
macroeconomic policies (Moorthy, 1989/90; Keil and Symons, 1990). However, with
the deterioration of the macroeconomic environment in the early 1980s, the higher
structural unemployment rate may no longer have been masked by cyclical factors, so
that Canada's higher structural unemployment rate relative to the United States may then
have showed up as a higher actual rate. Evidence supporting this "masking" hypothesis
is reported in Keil and Pantuosco (this volume).
Another possibility is that there are long lags between major changes in social
programs such as UI and the labour market consequences of these programs. Such long
lags could have several causes, including both individual and social learning about the
program and changes in "social norms" relating to the use of the program. Corak (1993)
and Lemieux and MacLeod (1994) report evidence for Canada supporting this
hypothesis. Evidence for other OECD countries is discussed in OECD (1994).
Although the 1971 reforms were arguably the most significant changes to
Canada's UI program in the past three decades, another change that has received
attention for its potential impact on unemployment is the introduction of regional
extended benefits (REB) in 1978. Milbourne, Purvis and Scoones (1991) point out that
these benefits make the maximum (or potential) duration of benefits, a dimension of UI
generosity, dependent on the actual unemployment rate, with a higher unemployment
rate leading to greater generosity. This dependence of UI generosity on the
unemployment rate can contribute to unemployment persistence if longer potential
benefit durations in turn result in higher unemployment. The attractiveness of this
explanation is that it could explain why the Canada - U.S. unemployment gap appears to
have emerged around the same time as the 1981-82 recession. To date, however, tests
have found little support for this "unemployment persistence" hypothesis.(15)
As was first pointed out by Ashenfelter and Card (1986), one of the most striking
differences between Canada and the United States is not in either the coverage or
'generosity' of their respective UI programs but rather in the probability of an
unemployed worker receiving UI benefits, as measured by the ratio of the number of UI
beneficiaries to the number of unemployed workers. Even before the 1971 reforms the
ratio of UI recipients to unemployed was two to three times higher in Canada than in the
U.S. During the 1980s, this gap widened; the ratio of UI recipients to unemployed
workers rose from about 80 percent to 100 percent in Canada but declined from
approximately 35 to 29 percent in the United States (Card and Riddell, 1993, Table
5.12). Thus in the early 1980s an unemployed Canadian was about twice as likely to
receive UI as his/her American counterpart; by the end of the decade the unemployed
Canadian was more than 3.5 times as likely to receive UI. The decline during the 1980s
in the probability of an unemployed worker receiving UI benefits in the United States
may be related to some of the administrative changes in the UI program discussed in
Andalfatto, Gomme and Storer (this volume).
In a recent paper, Card and Riddell (1997) find that in both countries UI
recipients are much more likely to report that they are engaged in job search than are
nonemployed individuals who are not UI recipients. These differences between UI
recipients and non-recipients in their reported "labour force attachment" when not
employed are large enough that changes in the fraction of the nonemployed who are UI
recipients can lead to substantial changes in the aggregate unemployment rate. Indeed,
calculations reported in Card and Riddell (1997) indicate that the divergent trends in UI
recipiency in Canada and the United States during the 1980s can alone account for about
two-thirds of the unemployment gap which opened up in that decade. Thus, whatever
factors caused the divergent intercountry trends in UI recipiency during the 1980s also
appear to be responsible for the increased labour force attachment of Canadians and thus
the Canada -U.S. unemployment gap.
The reasons for the substantial differences between UI recipients and non-recipients in their propensity to report their nonemployment time as job search remain an
interesting subject for further research. A number of explanations for these differences
seem possible. One is a pure "measurement" explanation. Because "availability for
work"-- which is often interpreted as requiring job search -- is a condition for continued
eligibility for UI benefits on both countries, recipients may be more likely to report
themselves as engaged in job search when surveyed by statistical agencies. A second,
closely related, explanation is that UI recipients are more likely to carry out job search
than are otherwise comparable non-recipients because of the "availability for work"
requirement. Another possibility is that UI recipiency is simply an "intervening variable"
rather than a causal factor and thus that the relative increase in Canada in UI recipiency
and the proportion of nonemployment time spent on job search are both caused by some
common underlying factor.
While the UI explanation of the emergence of the Canada-U.S. unemployment
rate gap may be germane for the 1970s and 1980s, its relevance to the current gap may be
more limited. This is because the relative generosity of the Canadian UI system has
fallen considerably in recent years. For example, Voyer (this volume) shows, based on
Sargent's (1995) UI generosity index, that UI generosity in Canada has fallen from a
peak of 240 in 1972 to 140 in 1994, to 80 under the recent employment insurance
reforms. This compares to a value of the index for the average U.S. state of 50 as of 1994
(Sargent, 1995). If in the past UI explained much of the unemployment gap, then the
decline in relative UI generosity would suggest that the gap should now be falling. Thus
far the experience in the 1990s has not been consistent with this prediction. There are
however a number of reasons why less generous UI may not immediately translate into
lower unemployment, as discussed above and in Sheikh (this volume).
Unionization
Over the last 25 years, one of the most dramatic developments in Canadian and
American labour markets has been the growing gap in the extent of unionization in the
two countries (Chaison and Rose, 1990; Kumar, 1993; Riddell, 1993). In 1965,
Canadian and U.S. unionization rates were roughly equal, at 30 per cent of the non-agricultural paid workforce. Union density increased somewhat in Canada in the 1970s
and in the first half of the 1980s, reaching a peak of 37.2 per cent of the non-agricultural
paid workers in 1984, and has subsequently declined modestly, to 33.9 per cent in 1996
(HDRC, 1996). In contrast, the unionization rate in the United States decreased
significantly in both the 1970s and 1980s and has fallen further, albeit modestly, in the
1990s (23 per cent in 1980, 16 per cent in 1990 and 14.5 per cent in 1996 (Bureau of
Labor Statistics, 1996). The Canada-U.S. unionization gap has thus increased from 4
percentage points in 1970 to to around 20 points in the mid-1980s and has since been
relatively stable.
Most economic models predict that the wage impacts of unions will reduce
employment and increase unemployment (Johnson and Layard, 1986). The limited
empirical evidence for Canada and elsewhere generally finds that employment growth is
slower in union than in comparable nonunion firms (Blanchflower, Millard and Oswald,
1991; Leonard, 1992; Long, 1993). Based on cross-sectional analysis of U.S. states, there
is also some empirical support for the prediction of a positive association between
unionization and unemployment (Summers, 1986). For these reasons, one might expect
the substantial divergence in the extent of union organization to have contributed to the
unemployment differential.
However, a difficulty with this prediction is that the unionization differential
began to open up in the mid 1960s and has progressively widened, whereas a persistent
unemployment gap does not appear until the early 1980s and this gap does not
progressively widen. This absence of correspondence between the timing of the gap in
unionization and that in unemployment led Ashenfelter and Card (1986) to reject
differences in union density as a possible explanation of the unemployment gap.
Subsequent research has generally supported this view. For example, in their analysis of
Canadian and American time series data, Keil and Pantuosco (this volume) find that
union density has little or no effect on unemployment in the two countries.
If trends in unionization did contribute to the unemployment gap, the impact
would probably be greatest in the 1975-85 period, when union density in Canada and the
United States diverged most sharply. Since the mid 1980s, the gap in the extent of union
organization has been relatively stable.
The predicted effects of unions on employment and unemployment arise
principally because of the impacts of unions on the level and speed of adjustment of
wages in the economy. Accordingly, in examining the evidence relating to possible
union effects, it is useful to look for any corroborating evidence of wage effects of unions
and other policies and institutions which may influence wages. This topic is addressed
next.
Wage trends
Labour demand is affected by the relative price of labour. The slower
employment growth in Canada relative to the United States since 1981, and especially
since 1989, could in theory reflect a larger decline (or slower rate of increase) in labour
compensation in the United States.
The data suggest such an explanation may have had some validity in the 1980s.(16)
The real producer wage, defined as business sector hourly labour compensation deflated
by the GDP deflator, rose at a 1.5 average annual rate between 1981 and 1989 in Canada,
compared to only 0.8 per cent per year in the United States. In addition, productivity
growth (1.3 per cent per year in the United States and 1.5 per cent in Canada) exceeded
real wage growth by a much greater amount in the United States. During the 1980s,
American employers thus had more incentive to expand employment than did Canadian
employers. The real consumer wage, defined as compensation deflated by the Consumer
Price Index, also grew at a faster rate in Canada in the 1980s.
A recent study of union wage determination in Canadian and U.S. manufacturing
provides further evidence of differential wage behavior in this sector of the two
economies (Budd, 1996). Although the behavior of union wages in the Canadian and
U.S. manufacturing sectors was similar in the 1965-79 period, during the 1980s wage
settlements in the United States were much lower than would have been predicted on the
basis of prevailing economic conditions whereas Canadian wage settlements were
approximately equal to those that would be predicted on the basis of economic
conditions. While concession bargaining was experienced by unions on both sides of the
border during the 1980s, the concessions were evidently greater in the United States, a
conclusion that has also been reached by others (Chaison and Rose, 1990; Kumar, 1993).
In the 1990s, the growth of real producer wages was similar in the two countries
(0.8 per cent per year over the 1989-96 period in Canada and 0.9 per cent in the United
States). Productivity growth tracked real wage growth fairly closely in both countries (0.5
per cent in Canada and 0.9 per cent in the United States). These developments suggest
that the rise in the Canada-U.S. unemployment rate gap after 1989 was not due to
differential trends in real wages in the two countries. However, it is important to keep in
mind that the 1990-92 recession was more severe in Canada than in the United States,
and that the subsequent recovery has also been slower in Canada. The fact that wage
trends have been similar in the two countries during this period suggests that the
responsiveness of wages to weak economic conditions may be lower in Canada, and this
could contribute to higher unemployment. The possible role of wage adjustment is
discussed further below.
Payroll taxes have increased greatly in Canada in recent years, rising from around
5 per cent of labour income in 1981 to over 10 per cent in 1994 (Di Matteo and Shannon,
1995). Some have argued that this trend has reduced employment growth and raised
unemployment. But payroll costs are included in labour compensation, and thus are
incorporated in the data presented which show real compensation growth in Canada has
not exceeded that in the United States. However, it is possible that the rapid growth of
payroll taxes has contributed to the evidently lower responsiveness of Canadian
compensation to weak economic conditions.
Trends in the minimum wages are another possible determinant of
unemployment. Over the 1980s, the minimum wage fell much more in the United States
than in Canada and this may have contributed to the fall in the unemployment rate in the
United States and the emergence of the unemployment rate gap. According to the OECD
(1997:13), the minimum wage fell from 46 per cent of average earnings in 1981 to 34 per
cent in 1989 in the United States, compared to a decline from 41 to 39 per cent in
Canada.(17) In the 1990s, there has been a rise in the relative minimum wage in both
countries, to 38 per cent of average earnings in the United States and to 42 per cent in
Canada by 1995. This suggests that the role of minimum wages in explaining the
unemployment rate gap may be less in the 1990s than in the 1980s.
Structural change
Structural (or frictional) unemployment is affected by the extent of the inter-sectoral reallocation of labour following shocks to the economy (Lilien, 1982). An
increased pace of structural change thus can raise the NAIRU and has been put forward
as a possible cause of the relative increase in Canadian unemployment.
The evidence for this hypothesis is weak. According to calculations made by the
OECD (1994), there has not been an acceleration of structural change in either Canada
or the United States. The Lilien measure of structural change, defined as the magnitude
of labour reallocation among sectors, as well as turbulence measures of structural change
were identical in both Canada and the United States in the 1970s and 1980s at the 8 or 9
sector level. Gera, Rahman and Arcand (1991) also found that the index of variation in
industrial employment growth has declined since the mid-1960s. This suggests that this
aspect of structural change has not contributed to a rise in unemployment in either
country.(18)
Personal taxes
According to OECD data, Canada's marginal tax rates in 1991-92 were 16.6
points higher than in the United States (55.5 per cent versus 38.5 per cent). This
represented a complete reversal of the situation in 1981 when American marginal rates
were 9.2 points higher than Canadian rates (50.4 per cent versus 41.2 per cent).
This change in marginal tax rates is reflected in trends in the share of personal taxes in
personal income. In Canada, this share increased from 18.0 per cent in 1981 to 20.5 per
cent in 1989, to 24.5 per cent in 1996, while it has been stable at around 13 per cent in
the United States.
Some argue that the emergence of the Canada-US unemployment rate gap is
related to these tax developments. Higher taxes in Canada are said to have stifled
entrepreneurial initiative, leading to lower investment, lower employment growth and
higher unemployment. Empirical evidence for this explanation is limited.
Demographic trends
The NAIRU is influenced by the changing composition of the labour force.
Increases in the relative importance of demographic groups with high unemployment
rates puts upward pressure on the NAIRU while decreases in the relative size of these
groups have the opposite effect. The demographic structures of the Canadian and
American populations are very similar, with both countries experiencing a baby boom
from 1947 to 1965. The entry of this baby boom generation into the labour market in the
1970s tended to raise the NAIRU because youth have well above average unemployment
rates. Equally, the decline in the youth (15-24 in Canada, 16-24 in the United States)
share of the labour force in both countries in the 1980s and early 1990s tended to reduce
the NAIRU. The reduction may have been slightly more in Canada since Canada
experienced a larger decline in its youth share because of relatively larger baby boom
cohorts. In any case, similar demographic developments in both countries have meant
that the rise in the unemployment rate in Canada relative to the United States since 1981
cannot be accounted for by this factor.
Immigration
In the 1990s, immigration levels to Canada have been well above those in the
1980s, and on a proportional basis, well above those in the United States. Because recent
immigrants experience a higher unemployment rate than the native born during the first
few years following arrival, some have speculated that these higher inflows of
immigrants may have contributed to the rise in unemployment in Canada in the 1990s
and to the widening of the unemployment gap in this period, given the relative stability
of legal immigration to the United States. However, the impact (if any) of immigration
on aggregate unemployment is complex, and at this point the evidence does not back up
the aforementioned speculation. Previous research in Australia, Canada and the United
States, three countries that have relied extensively on immigration as a source of
population growth, generally finds that immigration does not increase unemployment.(19)
Indeed, several studies conclude that immigration adds more jobs (though the effect on
labour demand) than immigrants take, so that the net effect of immigration is to lower
unemployment (see, e.g., Harrison (1984) and Pope and Withers (1993) for Australia and
Samuel and Conyers (1987) for Canada). The principal exception to the general finding
that unemployment is not positively related to immigration is Marr and Syklos (1994)
who find that immigration did not influence unemployment over the 1962 to 1978
period, but did have a small positive effect on unemployment during the 1978 to 1985
period.
Although the existing literature suggests that there is not a positive impact of
immigration on unemployment in either country, there are a number of reasons why
further investigation of this issue appears warranted. First, as noted above, immigration
inflows in Canada during the 1990s have been very high relative to the previous two
decades and relative to the U.S. Existing Canadian literature cited above covers only the
period up to 1990. Second, the recession of 1990-92 was the first economic downturn in
Canadian post war experience in which immigration inflows did not substantially
decline. The conditions governing the period on which the existing literature is based
were such that immigration inflows were significantly reduced during and following a
recession (such as occurred in 1957-9, 1971, 1973-4 and 1981-2).
A third factor is that the composition of Canadian immigration during the 1990s
has been much different than during the 1970s and 1980s, with the majority of
immigrants during the 1990s being in the family unification and refugee classes and the
minority being in the economically assessed class (those chosen for their suitability for
the Canadian labour market). For example, the proportion of immigrants who enter in
the economically assessed or "independent" class has fallen from 70 per cent in 1973 to
20 per cent in 1992 (Green, 1997). Those entering in the family unification and refugee
classes may have greater difficulty adjusting to the new labour market. For example,
Green (1997) finds that immigrants who are not assessed on their skills are in less skilled
occupations and are less occupationally mobile. Fourth, and perhaps related to the
previous point, there is evidence in both Canada and the U.S. that recent cohorts of
immigrants are adapting less well to the new labour market than was the case with earlier
cohorts (Baker and Benjamin (1994) and Bloom, Grenier and Gunderson (1995) for
Canada; Borjas (1995) for the U.S.).
Relative size of the incarcerated population
The relative size of the incarcerated population is about five times greater in the
United States than in Canada (1.0 per cent of the labour force versus 0.2 per cent in
1993) and this relative gap has increased over time.(20) Since the incarcerated have above
average unemployment rates before incarceration (40 per cent according to one survey),
their removal from the labour market reduces the overall unemployment rate. The greater
incarcerated population in the United States than in Canada results in a larger effect.
Back of the envelope estimates suggest that the high incarceration rate lowered the
unemployment rate by 0.4 percentage points in the United States in 1993, up from 0.2
points in 1980.(21)
In Canada, the impact is around 0.1 percentage points in both years.
These estimates suggest that the higher US incarceration rate accounted for about 0.3
percentage points of the gap in 1993, and for 0.2 points of the increase in the gap
between 1980 and 1993.
III Articles in This Volume
The papers in the volume are organized five sections- aggregate and regional
perspectives, labour market dynamics, labour market adjustment, labour supply and skills,
and policy implications. In addition, a summary of the overall findings of the conference and
papers is presented.
Aggregate and Regional Perspectives
Kevin Lang and Jay Zagorsky
A key issue in the debate on the Canada-US unemployment rate gap is its timing.
Did it only emerge in 1982 or do the roots of the gap date back to the 1970s? Lang and
Zagorsky use econometric time series tests to examine the high correlation between the
Canadian and U.S. unemployment rates and the timing of the emergence of the
unemployment gap.
They argue that the correlation between the two aggregate unemployment rates is
suspiciously high -- higher, for example, than that between most pairs of regions within
each of the two countries, such as California and Texas or Ontario and the Prairies. They
also conclude on the basis of statistical tests that the time series behavior of aggregate
unemployment in each country is reasonably approximated by a random walk. If so, the
high correlation between U.S. and Canadian unemployment could be spurious, in that
two random walks will appear to be highly correlated even if unrelated. If the random
walk hypothesis is approximately correct, analysing the unemployment rates in levels
may be misleading; rather, analysis of changes is preferred. When intercountry
differences in year-to-year changes in unemployment are examined, 1982 does not stand
out as a particularly unusual year. On this basis, they conclude that there is not a strong
case for focusing on events around 1982 in seeking explanations of the unemployment
differential.
The Lang and Zagorsky analysis is controversial. Because policy concern is
focused on the level of the unemployment rate, it is natural to devote attention to
intercountry differences in levels rather than year-to-year changes. Analysing year-to-year changes may seem like a less informative exercise. Furthermore, because it is
bounded by zero and 100 per cent, it cannot be the case that the unemployment rate
follows a random walk. The issue is whether a random walk is a reasonable
approximation to the time series behavior of unemployment. The statistical tests
reported by Lang and Zagorsky do not reject the random walk hypothesis, but these tests
may have low power (that is, the ability to reject this hypothesis with a relatively short
time series of data may be quite limited.)
Manfred Keil and Lou Pantuosco
Based on their analysis of five Canadian and nine U.S. regions, Keil and
Pantuosco conclude that the Canada-U.S. unemployment rate gap is a national
phenomenon rather than a region-specific phenomenon. They identify the principal
origin of the gap as being the 1971 liberalization of the Canadian UI system, but argue
that the impact of this development on Canadian unemployment was masked in the
1970s by favourable terms of trade movements and the expansionary effects of lax
monetary policy. Keil and Pantuosco also examine a number of other possible
explanations of the gap, and conclude that unionization rates, unemployment persistence
or hysteresis, taxes, and demographic changes have played little or no role.
Keil and Pantuosco's estimates indicate that the further widening in the gap in the
1990s was mainly caused by the increased real interest rate differential between Canada
and the United States during this period.
Labour Market Dynamics
Although unemployment is a "stock concept" - the number of unemployed as a
percent of the labour force at a point in time - much can be learned about unemployment
from the analysis of labour market dynamics - the flows among labour force states and
the durations of spells in each state. Two of the papers in the volume investigate aspects
of the incidence and duration of unemployment spells, while a third examines flows
among the labour force states of employment, unemployment and out-of-the-labour
force. These three papers document a variety of "facts" with which explanations of the
unemployment differential must be consistent.
A number of measures of the duration of unemployment exist. The average
duration of uncompleted spells, which was discussed earlier in this introduction, is the
most readily available but also generally the least informative. The papers by Baker,
Corak and Heisz and by Tille use measures of the duration of completed spells of
unemployment which are unpublished but can be calculated from LFS and CPS and
related microdata.
Michael Baker, Miles Corak and Andrew Heisz
Baker, Corak and Heisz use unpublished Labour Force Survey and Current
Population Survey data to calculate the incidence and average duration of completed
spells of unemployment for the 1980-93 period.
Canada experienced a relative increase in both incidence and duration of
unemployment over this period. In 1980-81, unemployment spells lasted about 2 weeks
longer in Canada than in the U.S., whereas in the latter half of the 1980s and in the 1990
these spells lasted 5 to 6 weeks longer in Canada. Even after allowing for the relative
rise in unemployment duration associated with the greater severity of the 1981-2 and
1990-92 recessions in Canada, an increase in the duration of unemployment in Canada
compared to the United States is evident.
In contrast, during the early 1980s the incidence of unemployment was
substantially higher - indeed, about one-third higher - in the U.S. However,
unemployment incidence declined steadily in the United States throughout the 1980s and
1990s, but (apart from cyclical fluctuations) was much more stable in Canada. For most
groups, unemployment was no more likely an event in Canada during the late 1980s or
1990s than a decade earlier, but it was much less likely in the United States.
Baker, Corak and Heisz also document substantial Canada - U.S. differences in
the composition of unemployment, with temporary layoffs and labour force entry being
more important in the United States and permanent job loss being a more important
source of flows into unemployment in Canada.
Cedric Tille
Cedric Tille also decomposes the rise in unemployment in Canada relative to the
United States into incidence and duration components. The contribution of the paper lies
in its innovative use of retrospective (as opposed to contemporaneous) data to compute
the average duration of unemployment in a year for those experiencing some
unemployment. In contrast to estimates of duration based on completed or uncompleted
spells of unemployment, this method examines the total weeks of unemployment
experienced during the year, whether experienced in several spells or a single spell. As
such, it provides a useful complement to spell-based analyses of incidence and duration.
Tille finds important gender differences in the factors contributing to the
unemployment rate gap. For men, higher relative unemployment in Canada is associated
principally with a relative rise in duration. However, for women the intercountry
unemployment gap is due mainly to a relative increase in the incidence of
unemployment.
Stephen Jones and Craig Riddell
Jones and Riddell provide a comparative analysis of aggregate labour market
dynamics in Canada and the United States using unpublished data on gross flows. Over
the 1976-94 period, they find many similarities in the behavior of gross flows in the two
countries, albeit there are some important differences. When the period is broken down
into pre- and post-gap periods (1976-81 and 1982-94), they find that the most substantial
relative change occurs in the transitions (in both directions) between the non-employment the states of unemployment (U) and non-employment (N). The transition
probability of moving from U to N falls by about 8 per cent in Canada relative to the
U.S., while the probability of moving from N to U rises by 23 per cent relative to the
U.S. What is noteworthy is that the emergence of the unemployment gap is not
associated with a relative change in the likelihood of moving between employment E and
non-employment (U plus N). Indeed, the probability of exiting from E actually declined
more in the U.S. than in Canada during the 1980s and 1990s, while the probability of
entering E declined by a similar amount in both countries.
In order to assess the quantitative importance of the relative changes in the
movements between the non-employment states U and N, Jones and Riddell carry out a
simulation in which the paths of the Canadian transition rates from U to N and N to U
follow their American counterparts over the 1982-94 period, adjusted for the average
differences in the levels of the two rates in the pre-gap 1976-81 period. Under this
scenario, almost all of the 1980s unemployment gap disappears and the 1990s gap is
reduced by 2 to 3 percentage points. This simulation reinforces the evidence reported in
Card and Riddell (1993, 1997) that the principal source of the unemployment differential
(especially during the1980s) is the relative change in how Americans and Canadians
spend their time when not employed, rather than relative changes in the likelihood of
employment between the two countries.
Labour Market Adjustment
Robert Amano and Tiff Macklem
Higher employer adjustment costs in European countries than in the United States
have been argued to be a contributing factor to the greater persistence of unemployment
in Europe. Differences in adjustment costs between Canada and the United States are
thus a natural candidate for consideration in the search for explanations of differences in
the behavior of unemployment in Canada and the U.S.
To tackle this issue, Amano and Macklem estimate dynamic linear-quadratic
models of aggregate labour demand for Canada, the United States and Germany. They
find adjustment costs to be an important determinant of labour market dynamics in all
three countries. But more importantly, they find that relative adjustment costs and the
speed of adjustment of labour demand are very similar in Canada and the United States.
As a consequence, their estimated models suggest that differences in employment
adjustment costs are unlikely to be a major factor contributing to the greater persistence
of unemployment in Canada.
Eswar Prasad and Alun Thomas
Another aspect of labour market adjustment is the degree of real wage flexibility.
Lower real wage flexibility in Canada relative to the United States is often advanced as a
possible explanation for Canada's higher unemployment rate. Prasad and Thomas use
vector autoregressive techniques to study the effects of aggregate labour market shocks
on employment, unemployment, real wages and labour force participation in Canada and
the United States. Their results indicate that shocks to employment growth result in
similar unemployment rate responses in the two countries, but lower real wage responses
in Canada. Nonetheless, Canada's lower degree of real wage responsiveness is not found
to be a significant factor contributing to higher persistence of unemployment in Canada.
David Gray and Gilles Grenier
As discussed previously, the duration of unemployment is greater in Canada than
in the United States. A key question is why this is the case. Gray and Grenier use data on
displaced workers in the two countries to examine the factors accounting for the longer
spells of joblessness experienced by these individuals in Canada. Their principal
conclusion is that there is nothing obvious in terms of the observable characteristics of
Canadian and American displaced workers, or in the way these individuals respond to
their economic environment, that helps very much in accounting for the longer jobless
spells experienced by such workers in Canada. Like the negative findings reported by
Amano and Macklem and Prasad and Thomas, the contribution of these results lies
mainly in suggesting that the explanation for higher Canadian unemployment lies
elsewhere.
Labour Supply and Skills
Peter Kuhn and Leslie Robb
Kuhn and Robb examine the role played by the declining demand for unskilled
labour in the emergence of the Canada-U.S. unemployment rate gap among prime-age
men in the 1980s. In both countries, wage polarization between the more and less skilled
was observed among prime-age men; the decrease in wages among the least skilled was
larger in the U.S., but nonetheless substantial in Canada. Kuhn and Robb find that the
evidence in both countries is consistent with the "labour supply response" hypothesis that
individuals respond to the lower returns from working by working less. Weeks worked
decline in both countries, and the decline is largest among those groups with the largest
declines in real wages.
Kuhn and Robb also address the hypothesis, advanced by the OECD and others,
that in countries like Canada with more generous social safety nets (and thus better
alternative opportunities to low wage employment), the decline in demand for unskilled
labour has meant that these individuals have been more likely to leave employment than
American men, while the latter have been more likely to continue working, albeit at
lower wages. According to this "OECD hypothesis" there is a tradeoff between earnings
inequality and employment in such circumstances of declining demand and in terms of
this tradeoff Canada has adopted a middle position between the extremes of Europe and
the United States.
Kuhn and Robb find that both aggregate and within percentile responses of weeks
worked to wage declines were larger in Canada than in the U.S. The combination
observed in Canada of smaller declines in real wages and larger declines in employment
is broadly consistent with the "OECD hypothesis". However, a further finding is that the
decline in employment mainly resulted in increased unemployment in Canada, but in the
U.S. it entirely took the form of increased labour force withdrawal. (Indeed, in the U.S.
average weeks worked declined by 1.0 weeks, but non-participation increased by 1.3
weeks so that unemployment actually fell by 0.3 weeks, whereas in Canada average
weeks of employment declined by 2.2 weeks, most of which was associated with
increased unemployment (1.7 weeks) and the remainder with reduced participation (0.5
weeks).
These results indicate that the "labour supply response" and "OECD" hypotheses
are able to account for the changing patterns of prime-age male employment in the two
countries, but these hypotheses do not help explain why the reduced employment mainly
took the form of increased unemployment in Canada but took the form of increased non-participation in the U.S. This relative change in how non-employment is "labelled" was
discussed previously in the context of the work of Card and Riddell (1993, 1997) and
Jones and Riddell (this volume). Kuhn and Robb show that this relative change in how
non-employment is reported in the two countries not only occurred during the 1980s for
prime age males as a group, but also at each decile of the wage distribution.
Audra J. Bowlus
The labour market behaviour of youth may be more revealing than that of older
age groups because youth, many of whom are making the transition from school to work,
may bear the brunt of structural and institutional change. Consequently, analysis of the
factors behind the gap for youth may contribute to an understanding of the overall
differential. Using the U.S. National Longitudinal Survey of Youth and the Canadian
Labour Market Activity Survey for 1986-87, Bowlus examines the labour market
behaviour of low-skilled males aged 20-24 in Canada and the United States. A key
feature of this study is the use of longitudinal data which allows analysis of the labour
market transitions of this select group. Although overall job separation rates are the
same in the two countries, she finds that young male Canadians are more likely than
Americans to be involuntarily separated from their jobs and the separation is more likely
to result in a transition to UI-supported non-employment. In contrast, young American
men are more likely to make a direct job-to-job transition. She suggests that two
interrelated features of the Canadian labour market contribute to this pattern: the greater
generosity of UI in Canada and the larger role of seasonal/temporary work in Canada.
David Andolfatto, Paul Gomme and Paul Storer
In searching for causes of the Canada-U.S. unemployment gap, attention has
focused on developments that raised the unemployment rate in Canada, such as changes
to the Canadian UI system. But developments that lowered the unemployment rate in the
United States could be equally at play. Using a dynamic computable general equilibrium
model of the labour market, Andolofatto, Gomme and Storer examine the effect on the
gap of changes in the U.S. UI system, in particular the introduction of taxation on UI
benefits between 1979 and 1987 and the administrative tightening of state UI during the
1980s. Their analysis suggests that each of these measures contributed a 0.2 percentage
point fall in the natural rate, thus accounting for 0.4 percentage points of the gap.
They also use their model to analyze the effects of implementing a Canadian UI
system in the United States, concluding that it would increase the U.S. natural rate 2.4
percentage points. They interpret their evidence as supportive of the view that the gap in
the 1980s is largely attributable to the 1971 liberalization of the Canadian UI program.
Paul Storer and Marc Van Audenrode
In addition to the rising unemployment rate gap, Canada and the United States
have experienced divergent trends in wage inequality, with the extent of inequality rising
considerably more in the United States. Storer and van Audendode try to link these two
trends as alternative manifestations of the economic shocks experienced in both
countries. The central hypothesis is that adjustment to adverse shocks primarily affects
wages in the U.S. but employment in Canada. They use retrospective data from the 1986
Canadian and American Displaced Worker Surveys to examine wages obtained after
displacement and length of time taken to find a job. They find meager support for the
hypothesis of a tradeoff between wage inequality and unemployment whereby low
unemployment in the United States was at the cost of greater wage inequality.
Papers on Implications of the Research Findings
The synthetic papers in this section were presented in the final session of the
conference on the implications of the research findings for policy. Two leading
academics, Gary Burtless and John Helliwell, and two senior government officials, Jean-Pierre Voyer and Munir Sheikh, give their views on the research presented at the
conference and the policy implications.
Conclusions
The principal findings of each of the papers in this volume and how these results
relate to the previous literature have been discussed above. In this concluding section we
briefly note a number of key points which appear to emerge from these findings.
1. Some of the unemployment gap is due to differences between Canada and the
United States in how unemployment is measured, as documented by Macredie (1996)
and Zagorsky (1996). Persons whose only job search method is "looked at job ads"
are classified as unemployed in Canada, but as not-in-the-labour force in the United
States. In 1993, if the U.S. definitions were used, the number of unemployed in
Canada would have been reduced by 114 thousand, 0.7 per cent of the labour force.
This factor accounted for 17 per cent of the gap and its relative importance has been
growing over time.
2. As discussed by Macredie (1996), discovering such measurement differences in
two surveys such as the LFS and CPS which are very similar in concept and design
requires detailed examination of survey instruments, interviewer instructions, and data
capture and imputation methods. Further investigation of other possible differences in
measurement appears warranted, though there is of course no guarantee that other
such differences would help explain the gap (i.e. would imply higher measured
unemployment in Canada). In addition, the introduction of a redesigned CPS in 1994
in the United States and a new LFS in Canada in 1997 mean that this issue of data
comparability has not been resolved for the post-1994 period.
3. The unemployment gap of the 1980s and the further widening of the gap in the
1990s appear to have fundamentally different underlying causes. The gap of the
1980s is principally due to a relative change in how Canadians and Americans spend
(or at least report) their time when not working rather than to a relative decline in
employment in Canada. The widening of the gap in the 1990s is principally due to the
much weaker aggregate economic growth in Canada during the 1990s, and the
consequent steep relative decline in employment in Canada. These observations are
elaborated in the following two points.
4. The 1980s gap of 2-3 percentage points emerged during a period in which overall
economic growth and employment growth was similar in the two countries. The
1981-82 recession was significantly more severe in Canada than in the U.S., which
suggests that a simple "cyclical" explanation can account for the steeper rise in
unemployment in Canada in the early 1980s. However, the subsequent recovery and
expansion in the latter part of the 1980s was also more robust in Canada. It is
therefore difficult to attribute the persistent unemployment gap of the 1980s to weaker
aggregate economic growth in Canada. Rather, the 1980s gap is attributable to a
relative rise in the "labour force attachment of the non-employed", as documented in
Card and Riddell (1993, 1997). This relative change took place between the late
1970s and late 1980s.
5. The further widening of the unemployment gap after 1989 appears to be mainly if
not entirely due to the much weaker aggregate economic growth in Canada since
1990. As is documented in Fortin (1996), Canada's recession of 1990-92 -- the most
severe since the Great Depression - was both substantially more pronounced and of
longer duration than the downturn in the United States. Furthermore, the subsequent
recovery has also been weaker in Canada. A straightforward "cyclical" story appears
to explain the widening of the unemployment gap in the 1990s.
6. The reasons for the relative change in the labour market attachment of the non-employed in Canada and the United States remain poorly understood. Card and
Riddell (1997) report that the change correlates well with changes in UI recipiency in
the two countries, though the causal mechanisms remain unclear.
7. The timing of the emergence of the unemployment differential remains a matter
of debate. One view, articulated in Fortin, Kiel and Symons (1995) and Kiel and
Pantuosco (this volume), is that the seeds of the gap were sown in the early 1970s with
the 1971-72 revisions to Canada's UI program. According to this view, a persistent
unemployment gap did not emerge during that decade due to offsetting favourable
macroeconomic conditions. Related to this perspective is the point made by Lang and
Zagorsky (this volume) that if it is appropriate to analyse Canada - U.S.
unemployment differences in first differences rather than in levels, the year-to-year
change from 1981-82 was not especially prominent.
8. The alternative view is that the sources of the gap are changes that occurred in the
1980s rather than the 1970s, such as the tightening of the U.S. UI program in the early
1980s discussed by Andalfatto, Gomme and Storer (this volume) or the (possibly
related) divergent trends in UI recipiency in the two countries during the 1980s.
According to this perspective, the unemployment differential initially emerged
because of the deeper recession in Canada in 1981-82, but then persisted because of
structural differences between the two countries that emerged later in the decade.
9. Discriminating between or reconciling these competing hypotheses is an
important topic for further research.
10. Many authors, including in this volume Bowlus, Keil and Pantuosco, Storer and
van Audenrode, and Baker, Corak and Heisz conclude that the more generous
Canadian unemployment insurance system produced different labour market
behaviour in Canada from that conditioned by a less generous UI system in the United
States. Despite this general agreement that UI contributes to the unemployment
differential, there is not consensus on the exact mechanisms or on the timing of the UI
effects.
11. Differences in the adaptability or flexibility of the Canadian and American labour
markets have often been argued to contribute to inter-country differences in
employment and unemployment outcomes. However, Amano and Macklem (this
volume) find that relative adjustment costs and the speed of adjustment are very
similar in the two countries.
12. Differences in the degree of wage flexibility are likewise often advanced as an
explanation of Canada - U.S. differences. The evidence on this issue is mixed. Using
aggregate data, Prasad and Thomas (this volume) do find lower real wage flexibility in
Canada, as does Budd (1996) with respect to union wage behaviour in the 1980s, but
Prasad and Thomas also report that this difference in wage responsiveness is not a
significant contributing factor to higher unemployment in Canada. Storer and van
Audenrode (this volume), using micro data on displaced workers, find no evidence
that shorter unemployment durations among workers displaced in the U.S. can be
attributed to greater wage flexibility in that country. However, Kuhn and Robb (this
volume), using micro data on prime age males, find both smaller wage declines and
larger employment declines among the less skilled in Canada, consistent with the
wage flexibility story.
13. A number of Canada - U.S. differences, including unionization, immigration,
payroll taxes and income taxation, have not been found to play a role in the
unemployment gap in research reported in this volume and elsewhere. Nonetheless,
for reasons discussed in this introduction, several of these factors appear to warrant
further investigation.
Policy Implications
Differences in the measurement of unemployment between Canada and the
United States have no direct policy relevance, but these need to be taken into account in
any comparisons of the relative performance of the two economies. Equally, persistent
differences in the way non-employed Canadians and Americans report their labour force
activities may not have policy implications, depending on whether these differences in
the reporting of activities are associated with differences in behaviour. If, in general,
non-employed Canadians have the same desire for work as non-employed Americans, but
Canadians are more likely to be receiving UI and to report their activities as searching for
work (due, for example, to the job search requirements for continued UI benefit receipt),
Canadians may not be worse off with a higher measured unemployment rate. In these
circumstances, the true amount of excess labour supply is the same in the two countries,
but more of the labour supply is categorized as out-of-the-labour force in the U.S. and
more is categorized as unemployment in Canada. In contrast, if the differences in how
individuals are categorized reflect differences in the desire for work among the non-employed, then the higher Canadian unemployment does have policy implications
because it implies greater excess labour supply in Canada.
The conclusion that the widening of the Canada-U.S. unemployment gap in the
1990s is principally due to weaker economic growth in Canada has important policy
implications. It implies that the factors that contributed to Canada's anemic growth since
1989 are in effect the policies that explain the rise in the unemployment rate and the
increase in the unemployment differential. There is at present a debate about the extent
to which the "Great Canadian Slump" -- as Fortin (1996) so aptly calls it - is due to the
Bank of Canada's restrictive monetary policy of the early 1990s (adopted to attain the
objective of price stability) versus other factors such as restructuring associated with
globalization, freer trade and technical change (restructuring that may have taken place
to a greater extent in the 1980s in the United States) and high Canadian interest rates due
to high levels of government debt relative to GDP and political uncertainty relating to the
possibility of Quebec separation. (See Fortin, 1996, who attributes much of the slump to
monetary policy, and Freedman and Macklem, 1997, who attribute it to a mix of factors.)
Whatever the causes of Canada's poor growth performance, a consequence has been
lower inflation and a key question for policy-makers is whether the benefits of price
stability have been worth the costs in terms of lost output and unemployment. This
question on the costs and benefits of price stability is not only of historical interest. It
may arise in the future if the need to maintain price stability is used as a rationale for
policies that stifle growth.
The conclusion that the widening of the gap in the 1990s is mainly due to weaker
aggregate demand conditions in Canada also suggests that approximately half of the
current differential of 4 to 5 percentage points could be eliminated with a return to and
continuation of stronger growth in Canada. In terms of structural factors, the Canadian
unemployment insurance program has been substantially altered through a series of
reforms during the 1990s, the most significant being those implemented in 1996. These
changes have reduced the generosity of the program relative to the past and to the U.S.
During the 1990s there has also been a steep decline in UI recipiency in Canada. The
evidence in this volume and elsewhere suggests that these developments should enable
Canada to achieve lower unemployment levels. Together with the "cyclical" component
discussed above, these structural changes suggest that more than half and perhaps as
much as three-quarters of the current gap could be removed by a sustained period of
stronger growth in Canada.
In this respect, we wish to note that that public policies such as unemployment
insurance should not necessarily be designed to minimize the unemployment rate.
Economic security and the distribution of well-being are also important determinants of
social well-being. The reduction in risk that social insurance programs may provide
increase societal welfare and this increase may more than offset any welfare losses
associated with a higher structural unemployment rate induced by social program
disincentives. The greater degree of social equity provided by social programs may also
be a highly valued characteristic of society. The aggregate welfare of Canadians may be
higher in a society with generous social programs and high unemployment linked to the
programs than in a society with less generous programs and lower unemployment. This
being said, the disincentive effects of social programs on employment should
nevertheless be recognized and monitored, and, where it is not too costly in terms of
other objectives to do so, minimized.
The emergence and persistence of the Canada - U.S. unemployment differential
has lead certain observers to conclude that Canada's labour market is less dynamic than
its U.S. counterpart and that Canadian policies and institutions result in a labour market
that is more rigid and less able to adjust to change. The findings in this volume suggest
that one should be cautious in drawing such a conclusion. Indeed, much of the evidence
does not support this position.
The key implication of the above analysis is that a return to and continuation of
stronger economic growth will go a long way toward reducing the Canada-U.S.
unemployment rate gap, particularly now that relative generosity of the Canadian social
safety net has been reduced.
References
Akyeampong, Ernest B. (1992) "Discouraged Workers - Where Have They Gone?"
Perspectives on Labour and Income, Volume 4, Autumn 38-44.
Altonji, Joseph G. and David Card (1991) "The Effects of Immigration on the Labor
Market Outcomes of Less-skilled Natives" in Immigration, Trade and the Labor Market
edited by John M. Abowd and Richard B. Freeman. Chicago: University of Chicago
Press.
Amano, Robert A. and R. Tiff Macklem (1997) "Unemployment Persistence and Costly
Labour Adjustment of Labour: A Canada-U.S. Comparison," This Volume.
Anderson, Rick and Mike Shannon (1996) "Regional Economies and the Canada-U.S.
Unemployment Rate Gap," paper presented at the CSLS/CERF Conference on the
Canada-U.S. Unemployment Rate Gap, February 9-10, Ottawa, Ontario.
Andolfatto, David, Paul Gomme and Pasul Storer (1997) "U.S. Labour Market Policy and
the Canada-U.S. Unemployment Rate Gap" This Volume.
Ashenfelter, O. and D. Card (1986) "Why Have Unemployment Rates in Canada and the
United States Diverged?" Economica, 53, pp. S171-95.
Baker, Michael, Miles Corak and Andrew Heisz (1997)"The Labour Market Dynamics
of Unemployment Rates in Canada and the United States" This Volume.
Baker, Michael and Dwayne Benjamin (1994) "The Performance of Immigrants in the
Canadian Labor Market" Journal of Labor Economics, July, pp 369-405.
Baldwin, John R., Timothy Dunne and John Haltiwanger (1994) "A Comparison of Job
Creation and Job Destruction in Canada and the United States" Statistics Canada,
Analytical Studies Branch, Research Paper No. 64, July.
Bloom, David E., Gilles Grenier, and Morley Gunderson (1995) "The Changing Labour
Market Position of Canadian Immigrants," Canadian Journal of Economics, 28,
November, pp. 987-1005.
Borjas, George (1995) "Assimilation and Changes in Cohort Quality Revisited: What
Happened to Immigrant Earnings in the 1980s?" Journal of Labor Economics, April, pp.
201-45.
Bowlus, Audra J. (1997) "A Panel Data Analysis of the U.S. Canadian Nonemployment
Rate Gap Among Young, Low Skilled Males" This Volume.
Blanchflower, David G., Neil Millard and Andrew J. Oswald (1991) "Unionism and
Employment Behaviour" Economic Journal 101 (July) pp. 815-34.
Budd, John W. "Union Wage Determination in Canadian and U.S. Manufacturing, 1964-1990: A Comparative Analysis" Industrial and Labor Relations Review 49 (July 1996)
pp. 673-89.
Bureau of Labor Statistics (1997) Employment and Earnings, January.
Burtless, Gary (1997) "Relative Unemployment in Canada and the United States: An
Assessment," This Volume.
Card, David (1990) "The Impact of the Mariel Boatlift on the Miami Labor Market,"
Industrial and Labor Relations Review, January, pp. 245-57.
Card, David and W. Craig Riddell (1993) "A Comparative Analysis of Unemployment in
Canada and the United States" in David Card and Richard B. Freeman (eds.) Small
Differences That Matter: Labor Markets and Income Maintenance in Canada and
theUnited States. Chicago: University of Chicago Press and NBER, pp. 149-189.
Card, David and W. Craig Riddell (1997) "Unemployment in Canada and the United
States: A Further Analysis" in B. Curtis Eaton and Richard G. Harris (eds.) Trade,
Technology and Economics: Essays in Honour of Richard G. Lipsey. (Cheltenham, U.K.:
Edgar Elgar), pp. 47-87.
Chaison, Gary N. and Joseph B. Rose (1990) "New Directions and Divergent Paths: The
North American Labor Movements in Troubled Times" Labor Law Journal 41 (August)
pp. 591-96.
Chapman, Bruce J., David Pope and Glenn Withers (1985) "Immigration and the Labour
Market" in The Economic Effects of Immigration on Australia edited by N.R. Norman
and K.F. Meikle. Melbourne: CEDA.
Council of Economic Advisors (1994) Economic Report of the President (Washington,
DC: US Government Printing Office).
Corak, Miles (1993) "Is Unemployment Insurance Additive? Evidence from the Benefit
Durations of Repeat Users" Industrial and Labor Relations Review 47 (October) pp. 62-72.
Cremieux, Pierre-Yves and Marc van Audenrode (1996) "Is theU.S./Canada
Unemployment Gap Truly Large? A Labor Flow Analysis" in Ronald Shettkat (ed.) The
Flow Approach to Labor Market Analysis. Rutledge, 1996,
Daly, D. and D. MacCharles (1986), "On real wage unemployment," Focus, No. 18, Vancouver,
BC: The Fraser Institute (June).
Di Matteo, Livio and Michael Shannon (1995) 'Payroll Taxation in Canada: An
Overview," Canadian Business Economics, Volume 3, Number 4, Summer, pp. 5-22.
Fortin, Mario (1994) L'ecart de chomage entre le Canada et les Etats Unis: analyse des
divergences entre les hommes et les femmes," L'Actualite Economique, Volume 70, Number
3, pp. 247-270.
Fortin, Pierre (1989) "How High is Canada's Natural Unemployment Rate," European
Economic Review,Volume 33, pp.89-110.
Fortin, Pierre (1996) "The Great Canadian Slump," Canadian Journal of Economics,
Volume 29, Number 4, November pp. 761-787.
Fortin, Pierre (1997) "Jobs and the NAIRU," paper presented to the John Deutsch
conference on the 1997 budget, April.
Fortin, Pierre, Manfred Kiel and James Symons (1995) "The sources of unemployment in
Canada, 1967-1991: evidence from a panel of regions and demographic groups"
Working Paper No. 45, Program in Economic Growth and Policy, Canadian Institute for
Advanced Research, Toronto.
Freedman, Charles and Tiff Macklem (1997) "A comment on "The Great Canadian
Slump", mimeo, Bank of Canada, Ottawa.
Freeman, B. Richard (1994) Crime and the Job Market, NBER Working Paper No. 4808,
October.
Gera, Surendra, Syed Sajjadur Rahman and Jean-Louis Arcand (1991) "Structural
Imbalances in Canadian Labour Markets," Working Paper No 18, Economic Council of
Canada.
Gordon, Robert J. (1997) "The Time-Varying NAIRU and its Implications for Economic
Policy," Journal of Economic Perspectives, Volume 11, Number 1, Winter, pp. 11-32.
Gray, David and Giles Grenier (1997) "Jobless Duration of Displaced Workers: A
Comparison of Canada and the United States" This Volume
Green, David A. (1997) "Immigrant Occupational Attainment: Assimilation and Mobility
Over Time" Journal of Labor Economics, forthcoming.
Grubel. H.G. and J. Bonnici (1986) Why is Canada's Unemployment Rate so High? A Labour
Market and Technology Explanation of the Divergence of Unemployment Rates in Canada
and the United States, Fraser Institute.
Harrison, David S. (1984) "The Impact of Immigration on a Depressed Labour Market:
The Southern Australian Experience" The Economic Record 60 (1984) pp. 57-67.
Human Resources Development Canada (1996) Directory of Labour Organizations in
Canada (Ottawa).
Johnson, George E. and Richard G. Layard (1986)"The Natural Rate of Unemployment:
Explanation and Policy" in Orley C. Ashenfelter and Richard G. Layard (eds.) Handbook
of Labor Economics. Amsterdam: North Holland, pp. 921-999.
Jones, S.R.G. (1995)Hysteresis in the Canadian Labour Market (Montreal: McGill /Queen's
University Press).
Jones, Stephen R.G. and Miles Corak (1995) " The Persistence of Unemployment: How
Important Were Regionally Extended Benefits," Canadian Journal of Economics, Vol. 28,
Number 3, August, pp. 555-567.
Jones, Stephen R.G. and W. Craig Riddell (1993) "The Measurement of Unemployment:
An Empirical Approach" University of British Columbia, Department of Economics,
Discussion Paper93-48, December.
Jones, Stephen R.G. and W. Craig Riddell. (1997)"Gross Flows of Labour in Canada and
the United States" This Volume
Helliwell, John (1997)"The Unemployment Rate Gap: Results, New Questions, and
Policy Implications" This Volume
Hostland, Doug (1996) "Measuring Cyclical Influences on the Canada-U.S.
Unemployment Rate Gap," paper presented at the CSLS/CERF Conference on the
Canada-U.S. Unemployment Rate Gap, February 9-10, Ottawa, Ontario.
Keil, Manfred and James Symons (1990) An Analysis of Canadian Unemployment,"
Canadian Public Policy, Volume 16, pp. 1-16.
Keil, Manfred and Lou Pantuosco (1997)"Canadian and U.S. Unemployment Rates: A
Comparison Based on Regional Data" This Volume
Kuhn, Peter and A. Leslie Robb (1997) "Shifting Skill Demand and the Canada-U.S.
Unemployment Rate Gap: Evidence from Prime-Age Men," This Volume.
Kumar, Pradeep (1993) From Uniformity to Divergence: Industrial Relations in Canada
and the United States. Kingston: IRC Press.
Lang, Kevin and Jay Zagorsky (1997) "Why Are Canadian and U.S. Unemployment
Rates So Highly Correlated?" This Volume.
Lemieux, Thomas and W. Bentley MacLeod (1994) "Supply Side Hysteresis: The Case of
the Canadian Unemployment Insurance System" mimeo, University of Montreal.
Leonard, Jonathan S. (1992) "Unions and Employment Growth" Industrial Relations 31
(Winter) pp. 80-94.
Lilien, D.M. (1982) "Structural Shifts and Cyclical Unemployment," Journal of Political
Economy, Vol. 90, No. 4, pp.777-793.
Long, Richard J. "The Impact of Unionization on Employment Growth of Canadian
Companies" Industrial and Labor Relations Review 46 (July, 1993) pp. 691-703.
Macredie, Ian (1996) "The Effects of Survey Instruments on the Canada/U.S.
Unemployment Rate Gap," paper presented at the CSLS/CERF Conference on the
Canada-U.S. Unemployment Rate Gap, February 9-10, Ottawa, Ontario.
Marr, William L. and Pierre L. Siklos (1994) "The Link Between Immigration and
Unemployment in Canada" Journal of Policy Modeling 16 (No. 1, 1994) pp. 1-25.
Mendelson, Michael (1996) "Lost Among the NAIRUs: Policy Consequences of
Explanations of the Canada-U.S. Unemployment Rate Gap,' paper presented at the
CSLS/CERF Conference on the Canada-U.S. Unemployment Rate Gap, February 9-10,
Ottawa, Ontario.
Milbourne, Ross D., Douglas D. Purvis, and W. David Scoones (1991) "Unemployment
Insurance and Unemployment Dynamics," Canadian Journal of Economics, 24, pp. 804-26.
Moorthy, V. (1989/90) "Unemployment in Canada and the United States: The Role of
Unemployment Insurance Benefits," Federal Reserve Bank of New York Quarterly, 14, pp.
48-61.
OECD (1994) The OECD Jobs Study: Evidence and Explanations. Paris: OECD.
OECD (1996) Canada: OECD Economic Surveys, November.
OECD (1997) Employment Outlook, July (Paris).
Pope, David and Glenn Withers (1993) "Do Migrants Rob Jobs? Lessons of Australian
History, 1861-1991" Journal of Economic History 53 (December, 1993) pp. 719-42.
Prasad, Eswar and Alun Thomas (1997) "Labour Market Adjustment in Canada and the
United States" This Volume.
Riddell, W. Craig (1993) "Unionization in Canada and the United States: A Tale of Two
Countries," in David Card and Richard B. Freeman (eds.) Small Differences That Matter:
Labor Markets and Income Maintenance in Canada and theUnited States. Chicago:
University of Chicago Press and NBER, pp. 149-189.
Samuel, T.J. and T. Conyers (1987) "The Employment Effects of Immigration: A
Balance Sheet Approach" International Migration 25 pp. 283-90.
Sargent, Tim (1995) "An Index of the Unemployment Insurance Disincentives," Working
Paper No. 95-10, Department of Finance.
Setterfield, M.A., D.V. Gordon and L. Osberg (1992) "Searching for a Will o' the Wisp: An
Empirical Study of the NAIRU in Canada," European Economic Review
Volume 36, Number 1, pp. 119-136.
Sharpe, Andrew (1996) "The Canada-U.S. Unemployment Rate Gap: An Assessment of
the Causes," Research Paper R-96-15Ea, Applied Research Branch, Human Resources
Development Canada, July.
Sharpe, Andrew and Dragan Djelic (1996) "The Canada-U.S. Unemployment Rate Gap:
A Compendium of Recent Studies," Research Paper R-96-15Eb, Applied Research
Branch, Human Resources Development Canada, July.
Sheikh, Munir (1997) "Structural and Macro Policy and the Canada-U.S. Unemployment
Rate Gap," This Volume.
Staiger, Douglas, James H. Stock and Mark W. Watson (1997) "The NAIRU.
Unemployment and Monetary Policy, Journal of Economic Perspectives, Volume 11,
Number 1, Winter, pp. 33-50.
Stanford, Jim (1995) " Bending Over Backwards: Is Canada's Labour Market realyy
Flexible," Canadian Business Economics, Volume 4, Number 1, Fall, pp. 70-87.
Statistics Canada (1993) Adult Correctional Services in Canada, 1991-92, cat. 85-211,
Canadian Centre for Justice Statistics, February.
Storer, Paul (1992) "Persistent Unemployment and Sectoral Shocks in the Wake of the 1982
Recession," document de travail, Departement de sciences economique, UQAM.
Storer, Paul A, and Marc A. Van Audenrode (1997) "Exploring the Links between Wage
Inequality and Unemployment: A Comparison of Canada and the U.S." This Volume.
Summers, Lawrence (1986) "Why Is the Unemployment Rate So Very High Near Full
Employment?" Brooking Papers on Economic Activity, 2, pp. 339-396.
Tille, Cedric (1997) "Decomposition of the Unemployment Gap between Canada and the
United States: Duration or Incidence?" This Volume
Voyer, Jean-Pierre (1997) "Comments on the Canada-U.S. Unemployment Rate Gap
Conference," This Volume.
Withers, Glenn and David Pope (1985) "Immigration and Unemployment" The
Economic Record 61 (1985) pp. 554-63.
Zagorsky, Jay (1996) "The Effects of Definitional Differences on U.S. and Canadian
Unemployment Rates," Canadian Business Economics, Volume 4, Number 2, Winter.
pp. 13-21.
Table A1
Unemployment by Region in Canada and the Canada-U.S.
Unemployment Rate Gap, 1981-96
(per cent or percentage points)
  |
1981 |
1989 |
1996 |
UR |
region-US |
UR |
region-US |
UR |
region-US |
Atlantic |
11,5 |
3,9 |
12,2 |
6,9 |
13,9 |
8,5 |
Quebec |
10,4 |
2,8 |
9,3 |
4 |
11,8 |
6,4 |
Ontario |
6,6 |
-1 |
5,1 |
-0,2 |
9,1 |
3,7 |
Prairies |
4,5 |
-3,1 |
7,4 |
2,1 |
7,6 |
2,2 |
BC |
6,7 |
-0,9 |
9,1 |
3,8 |
8,9 |
3,5 |
Canada |
7,5 |
-0,1 |
7,5 |
2,2 |
9,7 |
4,3 |
Note: UR denotes the unemployment rate. The U.S. unemployment rate was 7.6 per cent
in 1981, 5.3 per cent in 1989 and 5.4 per cent in 1996.
Sources: Labour Force Historical Review, CD ROM version, Statistics Canada, February
1997.
Table A2
Duration and Incidence of Unemployment in Canada
and the United States, 1976-96
  |
average duration in weeks |
incidence (% of labour force) |
Canada |
U.S. |
Canada |
U.S. |
1976 |
13,9 |
15,8 |
26,6 |
25,3 |
1981 |
15,1 |
13,7 |
26,0 |
28,9 |
1982 |
17,3 |
15,6 |
33,0 |
32,3 |
1983 |
21,9 |
20,0 |
28,3 |
25,0 |
1984 |
21,5 |
18,2 |
27,3 |
21,5 |
1985 |
21,6 |
15,6 |
25,3 |
24,0 |
1986 |
20,3 |
15,0 |
24,6 |
24,2 |
1987 |
20,5 |
14,5 |
22,5 |
22,2 |
1988 |
18,2 |
13,5 |
22,2 |
21,2 |
1989 |
17,8 |
11,9 |
21,9 |
23,0 |
1990 |
16,8 |
12,1 |
24,9 |
23,7 |
1991 |
19,3 |
13,8 |
27,6 |
25,3 |
1992 |
22,6 |
17,9 |
25,9 |
21,5 |
1993 |
25,1 |
18,1 |
23,2 |
19,6 |
1994 |
25,7 |
18,8 |
21,0 |
16,9 |
1995 |
24,3 |
16,6 |
20,4 |
17,5 |
1996 |
24,0 |
16,7 |
21,0 |
16,8 |
Source: United States: Table B-40, Economic Report of the President, February, 1996;
Canada: Labour Force Annual Averages, Statistics Canada, various issues.
Note: Incidence is calculated at annual average unemployment multiplied by the number
of weeks in the year (52) divided by average duration of unemployment, with this
number expressed as a percentage of the labour force.
Table A3
Long Term Unemployment as a Share of the Unemployed in Canada
and the United States, 1981-96
(persons unemployed 27 weeks or more as a share of the unemployed)
  |
Canada |
United States |
1981 |
15,6 |
14,0 |
1982 |
19,8 |
16,6 |
1983 |
28,0 |
23,9 |
1984 |
26,1 |
19,1 |
1985 |
25,6 |
15,4 |
1986 |
23,5 |
14,4 |
1987 |
23,6 |
14,0 |
1988 |
20,2 |
12,1 |
1989 |
20,1 |
9,9 |
1990 |
18,5 |
10,1 |
1991 |
23,3 |
13,0 |
1992 |
28,1 |
20,6 |
1993 |
30,7 |
20,4 |
1994 |
30,2 |
20,3 |
1995 |
27,1 |
17,3 |
1996 |
27,1 |
17,4 |
Source: United States: Table B-42, Economic Report of the President, February, 1995;
Canada: Labour Force Annual Averages, Statistics Canada, various issues.
Table A4
Job Losses and Gains in Canada and the United States
(average annual rate as a share of total employment)
  |
1983-89/84-88 |
1989-91 |
Canada |
U.S. |
Canada |
U.S. |
gross job gains |
14,9 |
13,2 |
13,4 |
12,6 |
  |
openings |
3,2 |
8,9 |
3,4 |
7,4 |
expansions |
11,7 |
4,3 |
10 |
5,1 |
gross job losses |
-10,1 |
-10 |
-16,5 |
-11,1 |
  |
closures |
-2,8 |
-7,2 |
-3,7 |
-7,6 |
contractions |
-7,3 |
-2,9 |
-12,8 |
-3,5 |
net change |
4,8 |
3,2 |
-3,1 |
1,4 |
  |
net entry |
0,3 |
1,7 |
-0,3 |
-0,1 |
net expansion |
4,4 |
1,4 |
-2,8 |
1,6 |
turnover |
25,0 |
23,2 |
29,2 |
23,7 |
Source: Table 1.8, p. 17, OECD Jobs Study, Part I.
FOOTNOTES
1. Real output advanced 27.7 per cent in Canada compared to 22.9 per cent in the United
States between 1962 and 1966. Between 1973 and 1976, real output rose 13.7 per cent in
Canada compared to only 3.4 per cent in the United States.
2. See Akyeampong (1992) for a discussion of some of the reasons for the decline in the relative importance of discouraged workers during the 1990s.
3. This reinforces the finding of Card and Riddell (1993) that addition of discouraged
workers to the unemployed during the 1979-86 period raised the unemployment rate by
8-10 percent in each country but left the cyclical and trend components of each series
unaffected.
4. In 1981, the male unemployment rate was slightly lower in Canada than in the United States (-0.3 points), while the female unemployment rate was higher (0.4 points). In 1989, both unemployment rates were significantly higher in Canada -- 2.1 points for the male rate and 2.4 points for the female rate. Thus in 1989 the female unemployment rate was slightly more important in accounting for the unemployment rate gap than the male rate, but between 1981 and 1989 the male unemployment rate contributed slightly more to the increase in the gap, given the larger increase in the male gap (2.4 versus 2.0 points). Overall, these differences are minor and the key point is that the gap is explained by increases in both unemployment rates in the 1980s.
In the 1990s, the male unemployment rate increased more in Canada than the female rate (2.6 percentage points versus 1.6). Men thus accounted for a greater proportion of the additional increase in the Canada-U.S. unemployment rate gap than did women. Indeed, the male Canada-U.S. unemployment rate gap in 1996 was 4.5 percentage points, up 2.4 points from 1989. In contrast, the female Canada-U.S. gap was 4.0 points, up 1.6 points from 1989.
5. In 1981, the Canadian youth unemployment rate was nearly 2 percentage points lower
than in the United States, the unemployment rate for the prime age group (25-54) was
virtually identical, and the rate for the 55 and over group was slightly higher. Between
1981 and 1989, the Canada-U.S. unemployment rate differential for youth rose 2.5
points, that of the prime age group increased 2.2 points and that of the older age group
2.1 points.
Between 1989 and 1996, the Canada-U.S. unemployment rate gap rose 3.8 points for
youth, 2.1 points for the prime-aged group, and 1.2 points for the 55 and older group. The
absolute size of the gap in 1996 was in the 4.1 to 4.8 percentage points range for all three
age groups.
6. The simple decomposition of the unemployment rate into incidence and duration components does not take account of possible multiple spells of unemployment experienced by the same individual during the year. In the presence of multiple spells, it is possible that the pattern observed here (a rise in average duration and decline in measured incidence) could be due to the same number of individuals experiencing fewer but longer spells of unemployment.
7. Unfortunately, because of the introduction of a redesigned CPS in the United States in
1994, post-1993 information on this issue is not available.
8. One reason that the breakdown of unemployment into frictional/structural and cyclical components may not be straightforward and simple is that an increase in deficient demand unemployment due to a demand shock can over time transform itself into increased structural unemployment.
There are a number of mechanisms which could lead to changes in the NAIRU following demand shocks. One is the deterioration of the skills, attitudes and habits of the unemployed with time spent unemployed. A second is that lack of training opportunities for the unemployed could lead to asymmetries in wage setting. A third is that aggregate demand contractions lower investment spending, reducing the capital stock, with the economy hitting capacity constraints in the upturn before the unemployed are re-employed. For a discussion of these potential sources of hysteresis or path-dependence and an assessment of their empirical relevance in the Canadian labour market see Jones (1995).
9. Table 6 provides two OECD time series on total economy output gaps estimated on the
basis of a production function approach for the 1989-94 period. The original series shows
a much greater increase in the relative Canada-US ouput gap between 1989 and 1994
than the revised series- 8.3 points versus 3.8 points.
10. Looking first at the original series, in 1981 the Canadian economy was basically at potential, with an output gap of 0.3 points. In contrast, the United States economy was operating 1.9 per cent below potential. The identical unemployment rates in the two economies at the time despite the lower level of capacity utilization in the United States is explained by their lower NAIRU. In 1989, the Canadian output gap was virtually identical (0.1 points) to that in 1981. In contrast, the American economy went from a situation of a deflationary gap in 1981 to one of an inflationary gap (2.2 per cent). The emergence of the Canada-U.S. unemployment rate gap between 1981 and 1989 thus coincided with a turnaround in the Canada-U.S. output gap differential from 2.2 points to -2.0 points. A 4.2 point increase in the relative output gaps between the two countries corresponded to a 2.2 percentage point rise in the unemployment rate gap. When the revised output gap series is used, the story changes drastically. According to this series, Canada was operating 3.6 per cent above potential in 1989, so the Canada-U.S. output gap differential was basically unchanged between 1981 and 1989. This implies that macroeconomic developments cannot account for the emergence of the unemployment rate gap in the 1980s.
11. Note that we distinguish here between two measures of labour force attachment: (i) the
labour force attachment of the source population, P(LF), the probability of being in the
labour force conditional on being in the population of working age, and (ii) the labour
force attachment of the non-employed, P(U|N), the probability of being in the labour
force conditional on being non-employed. A decomposition shown below makes clear
the relationship between these two dimensions of labour force attachment and the
unemployment rate.
12. Card and Riddell (1993) compare Canada and the U.S. in 1979 and 1986, while a subsequent study (Card and Riddell, 1997) compares the two countries in 1981 (the last year prior to the emergence of the unemployment gap) and 1989. Both studies use both retrospective and contemporaneous data on labour market activities. Both studies and both types of data conclude that over 80 percent of the unemployment differential can be attributed to the relative increase in the labour force attachment of the non-employed in Canada.
13. See, for example, the comparisons of key features of the two programs over the 1968-88 period in Card and Riddell (1993) or the summary measures of unemployment benefit
entitlement for the 1961-91 period reported in OECD (1994). The OECD measures of
benefit entitlement take into account income assistance or welfare benefits (including
Food Stamps) which may be available to those who exhaust regular UI benefits. Sargent
(1995) constructs an index of UI generosity which ranks the Canadian system
substantially more generous than that of a typical U.S. state system as of 1994.
14. One qualification to this statement (discussed below) relates to the regional extended benefit provisions introduced to the Canadian UI program in 1978. Although these provisions did not change during the 1980s, the REB provisions made the maximum potential duration of UI benefits a function of the unemployment rate. As a consequence, the sharp increase in unemployment associated with the 1981-2 recession also increased the maximum duration of benefits for many UI recipients. In this respect, the Canadian UI program became more generous during the early 1980s.
15. See Storer (1992), Card and Riddell (1993), and Corak and Jones (1995).
16. The real wage explanation of the gap was put forward in the mid-1980s by Daly and McCharles (1986) and Grubel and Bonnici (1986), but was rejected by Ashenfelter and Card (1986) and Fortin (1989).
17. The measure for Canada is the weighted average of provincial minimum hourly wage
divided by average hourly earnings in all industries. The measure for the United States is
the federal minimum hourly wage divided by average hourly earnings of production and
non-supervisory workers on private non-agricultural payrolls. The source is the OECD
minimum wage database.
18. Stanford (1995) reached different conclusion from those of the OECD Jobs Study. He found that the volatility of sectoral employment at the two digit level was greater in Canada than in the United States over the 1983-94 period, and in the 1983-88 and 1988-94 sub-periods. He also found that the volatility of sectoral employment changes increased in Canada between the 1983-88 and 1988-94 periods, while it decreased in the United States. To the degree that a higher unemployment rate is associated with greater incidence of structural change, Stanford's data provide support for the view that greater structural change in Canada relative to the United States has contributed to the Canada-U.S. unemployment rate gap.
19. See Harrison (1984), Chapman, Pope and Withers (1985), Withers and Pope (1985) and
Pope and Withers (1993) for Australia; Samuel and Conyers (1987) and Marr and Syklos
(1994) for Canada; and Card (1990) and Altonji and Card (1991) for the United States.
20. Freeman (1994) found that in 1993 the number of men incarcerated in the United States was 1.9 per cent the number in the male labour force and 8.8 per cent of the black male labour force. This number are up dramatically from the early 1980s. In Canada, the prison population is much smaller. For example, in 1991-92, the average population (including both males and females with the former accounting for the lion's share) of federal and provincial prisons was around 30,000 (Statistics Canada, 1993), equivalent to 0.2 per cent of the total labour force and 0.4 per cent of the male labour force (assuming all inmates are male). The relative size of the prison population has increased much less in Canada than in the United States in recent years.
21. It is obviously difficult to estimate the impact of incarceration on the aggregate
unemployment rate. If the average unemployment rate of the incarcerated population
before incarceration were the same as that of the overall population, then the impact of
incarceration on unemployment would by definition be nil. But the unemployment rate of
the incarcerated population before incarceration is well above average, both due to its
racial composition (a disproportionate number of the incarcerated in the United States
are black and blacks have well above average unemployment rates) and educational
attainment (a disproportionate number of the incarcerated have limited schooling and
the unemployment rate for those with limited schooling is also well above average).
A recent American survey of the labour force status of inmates prior to
incarceration found an unemployment rate of 40 per cent. Under this assumption, male
unemployment in 1993 would have been 529 thousand greater (0.76 per cent (0.4 x1.9
per cent of 69,632 thousand male labour force), raising the overall male unemployment
rate 0.7 points from 7.1 to 7.8 per cent, and raising the overall unemployment rate 0.4
points from 6.8 per cent to 7.2 per cent.
The U.S. prison population increased from around 250 thousand in 1970 to 500
thousand in 1980 to 1323 thousand in 1993 (Freeman, 1994: Figure 1). Under the 40 per
cent unemployment rate assumption, adding the 1980 prison population to
unemployment and the labour force would have increased the overall unemployment rate
only 0.2 points from 7.1 per cent to 7.3 per cent. Thus, without this increased
incarceration between 1980 and 1993, under this assumption, the unemployment rate
would have been 0.2 points higher in 1993 relative to 1980.
Since Canadian incarceration rates are only one fifth American rates, the impact
of incarceration of the Canadian unemployment rate is negligible (less than 0.1
percentage point). This means that in 1993 higher incarceration rate in the United States
account for about 0.3-0.4 percentage points or about 10 per cent of the gap. The
American unemployment rate is much more affected than the Canadian rate by the
transfer of many high-unemployment, low-skill men from the labour market to prison.
This phenomenon puts downward pressure of the American unemployment rate. The
increased incarceration rate in the United States between 1980 and 1993, compared to a
relatively stable rate in Canada, contributed about 0.2 points to the increase in the
Canada-U.S. unemployment gap. (In 1980, even though the unemployment rate were
similar, the higher incarceration rates in the United States lowered the unemployment
rate by about 0.2 points).
|